Two-Sided Markets

Pages437-469
437
CHAPTER XI
TWO-SIDED MARKETS
A. Introduction
Nightclubs and online dating companies provide services to men and
women who want to meet. Credit cards enable consumers who have
them and merchants that accept them to transact with one another. Video
game platforms, such as Sony PlayStation or Nintendo, provide software
tools that enable publishers to develop games and a device on which
consumers can play those games. In each case, the business provides a
platform that enables two distinct but related groups of customers to
obtain value. These “two-sided platforms” or “two-sided markets”
characterize a wide variety of industries.1
1. For a review of the literature on two-sided markets and antitrust cases
involving such markets, see TILBURG LAW AND ECONOMICS CENTER &
HOWREY LLP, MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS (2010), available at
www.nma.nl/Images/NMa%20Two-Sided%20Markets%20-
%20Report%20-%2016%20July%202010_tcm16-140396.pdf.
[hereinafter MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS]. See also E . Glen Weyl,
A P rice Theory of Multi-Sided Platforms, 100 AM. ECON. REV., 1642
(2010; David S. Evans & Richard Schmalensee, Industrial Or ganization
of Markets with Two-Sided Pla tforms, 3 COMPETITION POLY INTL 150,
152 ( 2007) [hereinafter Evans & Schmalensee, Industrial Organization]
(“Many diverse industries are populated by businesses that operate ‘two-
sided platforms.’ These businesses serve distinct groups of customers
who need each other i n some way, and the core business of the two -sided
platform is to provide a common (real or virt ual) meeting place and to
facilitate interactions between members of the two distinct customer
groups. Two-sided platforms are common in old-economy industries
such as those based on advertising -supported media and new-economy
industries such as those based on software platfor ms and web portals .
They play an important role throughout the economy by minimizing
transactions costs between entities that can benefit from getting
together.”). Many platforms have more than two groups of distinct users.
See David S. Evans & Michael Noel, The Analysis of Mergers That
Involve Multisided Platform Businesses, 4 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON.
438 Market Definition in Antitrust
In antitrust cases involving two-sided platforms, market definition
and market power analyses must take into account several economic
issues that do not arise in other contexts. The two sides of a platform
business are closely linked, with interdependent prices and outputs and
intertwined strategies. For example, if an online dating service increased
its prices to women, it would attract fewer women to its site. As a result,
it would lose male members and, with fewer men, even more women
would desert the service. As another example, credit card issuers offer
reward programs to persuade more people to use credit cards. As credit
card use increases, card issuers can convince more merchants to pay to
accept the card. To understand the relevant competitive relationships,
one must consider both sides of the platform business.
A platform can earn profits on either side. In practice, two-sided
platforms often obtain most of their incremental profits on one side and
may provide services to the other side at prices below incremental costs.
For example, video game platforms earn most of their profits “on game
developers through per-unit royalties on games and fixed fees for
development kits and treat the gamers side as a loss leader.”2
Most standard approaches to market definition, such as the small but
significant and nontransitory increase in price (SSNIP) test, diversion
ratios, and other economic models and formulae, do not apply to two-
sided markets without modification, occasionally radical in nature.3
663, 664 (2008) [hereinafter Evans & Noel] (“ Many old industries are
based on [multisided platforms or] MSPs, ranging from village
matchmakers that date from ancient times to advertising supported
newspapers introduced in the seventeenth century to payment cards
introduced in the mid-twentie th century. However, an increasing number
of significant modern businesses are MSPs as a result of technological
changes that have drasticall y lowered the costs and increased the benefits
of connecting diverse customer groups on a single platform. These
include most Internet-based businesses such as eBay, Faceb ook, and
Google. These businesses ar e creating new products and services such as
social networking platforms and are disrupting existing industries such as
advertising-supported media.”). This chapter focuses on two-sided
platforms, but most concepts extend readily to multisided platforms.
2. Jean-Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, P latform Competition in Two-Sided
Markets, 1 J. EUR. ECON. ASSN 990, 990-91 (2003) [hereinafter Rochet
& Tirole, Pla tform Competition].
3. David S. Evans, Competition and Regulator y P olicy for Multi-Sided
Platforms with Applications to the Web Economy, 2 CONCURRENCES 57
¶ 28 (2008) (providing an overview of two-sided platforms); E vans &
Noel, sup ra note 1, at 675 (explaining that “the one-sided Critical Loss
Two-Sided Markets 439
Many of these “standard tools of antitrust and merger analysis . . . were
developed based on the economics of single-sided businesses” and “do
not necessarily apply in ways that are material to the analysis of
competition that involves multisided businesses.”4 For example, one
common approachusing the price-cost margin on one side to assess
critical losstends to understate the effects of a merger on prices
compared with the two-sided market formula.5 Another approach
estimating demand elasticities directly based on a standard one-sided
modeltends to overstate the effects of a merger on prices.6
This chapter describes how two-sided platforms operate, explains the
basic economics of profit-maximization for two-sided businesses, and
notes some of the unique aspects of competitive strategies when one of
the rivals is two-sided. It summarizes key market definition issues,
shows the extent to which the use of standard techniques for two-sided
platforms can result in bias, and addresses some basic conceptual issues
for markets with two-sided platforms, such as how to measure output and
which firms to include in the analysis. Finally, it discusses cases and
agency decisions concerning two-sided markets.
B. The Economics of Two-Sided Platforms
A two-sided platform provides goods or services to two distinct
groups of customers who need each other in some way and who rely on
formulas for conducting the hypothetical monopolist test are wrong when
applied to two-sided markets”); Evans & Schmalensee, Industr ial
Organization, supra note 1, at 151 (“[P]rofit-maximizing prices may
entail below-cost pricing to one set of customers over the long run and, as
a matter of fact, many two-sided platforms charge one side prices that are
below marginal cost and are in some ca ses negative. These and other
aspects of two-sided platforms affect almost all aspects of antitrust
analysisfrom market definition, to the analysis of cartels, single-firm
conduct, and efficiencies.”).
4. Evans & Noel, supr a note 1, at 664 (“Each side of the MSP’s business
influences and constrains its strategies on the other side. Antitrust
analysis that focuses on one side of the business in isolation from the
other side is incorrect as a matter of economics, and can lead to the wrong
answer when indirect network effects ar e significant and are relevant for
assessing the practice at issue.”).
5. Id. at 682.
6. Id. at 670.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT