Innovation Markets

Pages471-502
471
CHAPTER XII
INNOVATION MARKETS
A. Introduction
In their joint Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual
Proper ty (IP Guidelines), the Department of Justice (DOJ) and the
Federal Trade Commission (FTC) state: “An innovation market consists
of the research and development directed to particular new or improved
goods or processes, and the close substitutes for that research and
development.”1 The distinguishing characteristic of innovation markets
is competition to develop new goods and services. Innovation markets
competition is competition in research and development (R&D) itself, as
opposed to traditional competition to sell existing goods and services.
Thus, unlike in traditional merger analysis, where the focus is largely on
competition in actual goods, in analyzing mergers in innovation markets,
the focus is on competition in potential goods.2
As the DOJ and the FTC state in the IP Guidelines, licensing
arrangements or mergers between companies may have competitive
effects on innovation that cannot be adequately addressed through the
traditional analysis of goods or technology markets.3 For instance, “the
1. U.S. DEPT OF JUSTICE & FED. TRADE COMMN, ANTITRUST GUIDELINES
FOR THE LICENSING OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY § 3.2.3 (1995) availa ble
at http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/guidelines/0558.pdf [hereinafter IP
GUIDELINES]. The Horizontal Merger Guidelines do not spec ifically
refer to innovation markets, but they do consider the possibility that a
merger will reduce competition in innovation. U.S. DEPT OF JUSTICE &
FED. TRADE COMMN, HORIZONTAL MERGER GUIDELINES § 6.4 (2010),
reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) 13,100, availab le at
http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/guidelines/hmg-2010.html [hereinafter
2010 MERGER GUIDELINES].
2. Rosa M. Abrantes-Metz, C hristopher P. Adams & Albert D. Metz,
Empirical F acts and Innova tion Markets: Analysis of the Phar maceutical
Industry, THE ANTITRUST SOURCE, Mar. 2005, at 1.
3. “Technology markets consist of . . . technologies or goods that are close
enough substitutes significantly to constrain the exercise of market power
472 Market Definition in Antitrust
arrangement may aff ect the development of goods that do not yet exist”
or, alternatively, “affect the development of new or improved goods or
processes in geographic markets where there is no actual or likely
potential competition in the relevant goods.”4
The earliest official statement that relevant antitrust marketscould be
defined around R&D activities was in the National Cooperative Research
Act (NCRA) of 1984.5 As part of NCRA, Congress mandated that
cooperative research be subject to an evaluation of competitive effects
“in properly defi ned, relevant research, development, product, process
and service markets.”6
Innovation markets were first alleged by the FTC in 1990, when it
opposed Roche’s acquisition of a controlling interest in Genentech.7 At
the time, Roche and Genentech had overlapping manufacturing or
research interests in three therapeutic areas: Vitamin C, human growth
hormone, and CD-4-based AIDS/HIV treatments. As discussed in
greater detail in part E.1 below, the FTC alleged that the acquisition
would lessen competition in the research, development, production, and
marketing in these three therapeutic areas.8
However, the term “innovation markets” was not used until 1993,
when the DOJ opposed the merger between Allison Transmission, a
division of General Motors, and ZF Friedrichshafen, both leading
manufacturers of medium and heavy automatic transmissions for
commercial and military vehicles.9 The DOJ alleged several relevant
markets, includinga worldwide “innovation market.”10 According to the
DOJ, the production facilities of the merging firms were specialized
assets that were essential to the testing of innovations in that market.
In 1994, the DOJ opposed on similar grounds the merger between
Flow International and Ingersoll-Rand’s Waterjet Cutting Systems
with respect to the intellectual property that is licensed.” IP GUIDELINES,
supra note 1, § 3.2.2, at 8-10.
4. Id. § 3.2.3, at 10-11.
5. 15 U.S.C. § 4302.
6. Id.; see also Richard T. Rapp, The Misapplication of the Innovation
Market Approach to Merger Analysis, 64 ANTITRUST L.J. 19, 21 (1995).
7. Complaint, Roche Holdings, 113 F.T.C. 1086 (1990).
8. The firms later entered into a consent decree, whereby Genentech
divested its Vita min C interests and Roche divested its human growth
hormone business. See part E in this chapter for an expanded discussion.
9. Complaint, United States v. Gen. Motors, Ci v. No. 93-530 (D. Del. Nov.
16, 1993).
10. Id. 39.
Innovation Markets 473
division.11 The DOJ asserted that competition between these two firms
extended to R&D and technological innovation, both of which would be
harmed by the merger.12 Subsequently, the FTC has brought complaints
against a number of other mergers on the basis of harm to competition in
innovation markets.
One of the most important mergers involving innovation markets
was Genzyme’s acquisition of Novazyme in 2001. Genzyme was a large
biotech company with sales of nearly $1 billion at the time of the
acquisition, while Novazyme was a small startup company with no
products on the market.13 Genzyme and Novazyme were the only two
companies known to be working on treatments for a rare and debilitating
genetic ailment called Pompe Disease. Therefore, unequivocally, the
merger would have left Genzyme as the only firm with a research
program to develop treatments for Pompe.
The FTC had to decide whether this merger would harm competition
and should, therefore, be challenged. After a lengthy investigation, the
FTC voted in 2004 to close its investigation of the transaction. Timothy
J. Muris, the then-FTC Chairman, summarized his views in support of
closing the investigation as follows:
[N]either economic theory nor empirical research supports an inference
regarding the merger’s likely effect on innovation (and hence patient
welfare) based simply on observing how the merger changed the
number of independent R&D p rograms. Rather, one must examine
whether the merged firm was likely to have a reduced incentive to
invest in R&D, and also whether it was likely to have the ability to
conduct R&D more successfully.14
The discussion below highlights the economic theory behind
innovation markets, as well as its inherent difficulty and limitations. In
addition, the chapter describes the issues that arise in defining an
11. Co mplaint, United States v. Flow Int’l & Ingersoll-Rand Co., Civ. No.
94-71320 (E.D. Mich. Apr. 14, 1994).
12. See United States v. Flow Int’l Corp., 6 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 45094,
at 44,682 (E.D. Mich. 1994) (describing role of innovation market theory
in challenge to transaction).
13. State ment of Chairman T imothy J. Muris at 8, In r e Genzyme
Corporation/Novazyme Pharmaceuticals, Inc., No. 021-0026 (Jan. 1 3,
2004), availa ble at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2004/01/murisgenzymestmt.pdf
[hereinafter Muris Statement] . See parts C.1-2 and E.1 for a more
detailed discussion of the Genzyme/Novazyme merger.
14. Muris Sta tement, supra note 13, at 5-6 (footnote omitted).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT