Transportation Markets

Pages203-275
203
CHAPTER VI
TRANSPORTATION MARKETS
A. Introduction
Transportation includes a number of different industries that may
present very different issues in terms of market definition. The general
principles of market definition, which are described in Chapter I, are the
same for all these industries, but the questions that arise in their
application may be very different. These questions differ depending on
whether the transport in question is of people or freight and whether the
industry provides a fixed infrastructure that serves a network of routes,
such as railroads and pipelines, or operates vehicles over an externally-
provided infrastructure, such as trucking. Despite these differences,
certain issues, such as source competition, occur in a number of these
industries. Moreover, competition between these industries may be at
issue in market definition. The next section of this chapter discusses
market definition in the airline industry. Subsequent sections discuss
rail, intercity trucking, ocean shipping, and pipelines.
B. Passenger Airline Industry
1. Industry Background
Market definition in the airline industry is shaped by the elimination
of most regulation and subsequent developments in revenue management
and route planning, such as the creation of hubs. The industry differs
from many other industries because differentiated pricing (charging
different passengers or freight a different price for the same or similar
services) is possible and may lead to narrow markets. Regulation has
played an important role in airline travel over the years and has affected
the analysis of antitrust markets. It is therefore useful to discuss the
204 Market Definition in Antitrust
history of deregulation and some of the changes that were brought about
by deregulation before discussing markets.
Passenger airlines were deregulated with the passage of the Airline
Deregulation Act (Act) in 1978.1 Before the Act was passed, all mergers
were reviewed by the Civil Aeronautics Board (CAB) under a “public
interest” standard that did not place significant weight on competitive
effects. The Act changed the standard to include traditional antitrust
language similar to that in the statutes for non-airlines.2 The Act also
reduced fare regulation and entry and exit restrictions, and these changes
affected the development of market definition in the passenger airline
industry.
The elimination of regulated airfares led carriers to seek innovative
ways to maximize profits on individual flights. In the early 1980s,
American Airlines, under then-President Robert Crandall, developed one
of the first “revenue management” systems. This system was based on
research that showed that business travelers who were willing to pay
higher prices and were less likely to use alternative means of
transportation were also the ones who purchased tickets at the last minute
and traveled in “prime times” such as early morning and late afternoon.
If airlines filled planes during those prime business hours with
passengers who were traveling on vacation, they would not have capacity
for the business travelers who were willing to pay higher prices.
Furthermore, leisure travelers were more willing to take a mid-day flight
or use alternative means of transportation. Observing these tendencies,
American Airlines began charging the more flexible (elastic) leisure
passengers a lower price, and increasing the price for the less flexible
(inelastic) business travelers.
Other airlines adopted similar systems. To segregate the two classes
of passengers, the airlines developed restrictions on leisure travel, such
as requiring advance purchase or a Saturday stay to obtain a lower price.
1. Airline Deregulation Act of 1978, Pub. L. No. 95-504, 92 Stat. 1705
(current version at 49 U.S.C. § 40101 et seq.).
2. The Act prohibited the CAB from approving transactions which would
result i n, or be in furtherance of, a conspiracy or combination to
monopolize air transportation in any region of the United States. It also
prohibited the CAB fro m approving transactions which would
substantially lessen competition or tend to create a monopoly unless the
CAB found that the anticompetitive effects of the proposed transaction
were out weighed b y the public interest. H.R. REP. NO. 95-1779 (1978)
(Conf. Rep.), summary available at http://thomas.loc.gov/cgi-
bin/bdquery/z?d095:SN02493:@@@D&summ2=m&.
Transporta tion Markets 205
Initially, the airlines were unable to eliminate arbitrage between business
and leisure passengers and thus were unable to capture all of the
revenues from their differential pricing. Exchanges sprang up whereby
leisure passengers who could not use their tickets would sell them to
business travelers who purchased them at the last minute, thus depriving
the airline of the higher fare. Arbitrage ended when the federal
government began requiring all passengers to show identification that
matched the name on the ticket.3 Ultimately, the airlines refined the
revenue systems to offer a host of prices, increasing prices as the time of
the flight approached if seats were filling rapidly, or decreasing them if
they were not.
Before deregulation, airline routes were mostly point-to-point. Entry
or exit onto new routes was regulated by the CAB. Following the
passage of the Act, carriers generally were free to select their domestic
route systems at will.4 Carriers began forming “hubs” or airports from
which a number of “spokes” were flown such that passengers could take
a spoke from one city to the hub, change planes, and continue their trip to
the endpoint of another spoke. For example, connecting passengers
traveling to a variety of endpoints would combine with local passengers
on the flight to the hub, thus increasing the number of passengers flown
on that leg. Similarly, the flight from the hub would hold connecting
passengers from numerous origins traveling to the destination of that
flight. Hub and spoke systems are profitable for airlines because larger
aircraft required to serve an increased number of passengers on each leg
are more efficient per passenger to fly. The increase in the number of
passengers on legs to and from hubs also permits carriers to increase the
frequency of flights, which in some cases offsets the time the passengers
lost changing planes at the hub.
Some supporters of the Act based their position in part on the
economic theory of contestability. Initially, many believed that airline
routes were contestable (i.e., potential competitors could discipline
pricing) because airlines had low sunk costs and could easily shift planes
3. The Federal Aviation Admini stration issued a Security Directive in 1996,
which mandated that the airlines req uest identification. Letter from
Cathal L. Flynn, Assoc. Adm’r for Civil Aviation Sec., Fed. Aviation
Admin., to Robert Ellis Smith, Publi sher, Privacy Journal (Mar. 13 ,
1996), availa ble at http://epic.org/privacy/faa/letter.html.
4. Some restrictions on ser vice to small communities were maintained
following deregulation, and some airports did not have space available
for additional flights.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT