Manufacturing Input Markets

Pages49-89
49
CHAPTER II
MANUFACTURING INPUT MARKETS
A. Introduction
Antitrust cases often involve products or services that are used to
produce final products.1 These “intermediate goods” or “inputs” are
typically combined with other inputs, such as raw materials, labor, or
capital to produce “downstream” products. For example, certain grades
of steel may be made from scrap, electricity, labor, etc., so a steel maker
is a buyer of these inputs. However, most types of steel are themselves
used as inputs to make parts that are eventually assembled into final
products, such as cars, refrigerators, and bridges. Inputs can differ
substantially in the number of products or services in which they are
used, their importance in the production of downstream products, and the
number of levels of production and distribution that exist between
production of the input and sale of the final products.
Relevant market definition has been a key issue in the competitive
analysis of a multitude of antitrust cases involving intermediate goods
such as coal,2 crude oil,3 glass containers,4 lead5 and, as detailed in this
chapter, steel and chemicals. Although the basic economics of market
definition can be applied to inputs, important differences between inputs
and final goods can affect market definition.
1. There can be competitive concer ns involving either product or services.
For simplicit y, this chapter should be read to include services when the
terms “product” or “products” are used, unless otherwise stated.
2. See Chapter IV; see a lso, e.g., FTC v. Arch Coal, Inc., 329 F. Supp. 2d
109, 119 -23 (D.D.C. 2004); Kenneth G. Elzinga & Thomas F. Hogarty,
The Problem of Geographic Market Revisited: The Ca se of Coal, 23
ANTITRUST BULL. 1 (1978).
3. See Chapter IV; John Hayes, Carl Shapiro & Robert Town, Market
Definition in Crude Oil: Estimating the Effects of the BP/Arco Merger
(Aug. 2001) (unpublished manuscript), ava ilable at
http://www.ftc.gov/bc/gasconf/comments2/oilpaperjohnhayesetal.pdf.
4. FTC v. Owens-Illinois, Inc., 681 F. Supp. 27, 34-47 (D.D.C. 1988).
5. RSR Corp. v. FTC, 602 F.2d 1317, 1320-22 (9th Cir. 1979).
Market Definition in Antitrust
50
This chapter discusses some of the general considerations of market
definition relating to manufacturing inputs. It then addresses market
definition in two industriessteel in section B and chemicals in section
C. To illustrate the complete process of market definition for inputs,
much of section B examines in detail market definition in an older
litigated steel merger and an important recent merger resolved by
consent. Section C presents an overview of several important
intermediate goods market definition issues in the context of a variety of
chemicals cases.
1. The Economics of Input Markets
Input markets are defined using the same general principles
discussed in Chapter I, but these markets do raise a number of particular
issues. For example, in the case of inputs, it is important to evaluate
economic conditions downstream from the production of that input. The
Merger Guidelines explicitly refer to taking into account downstream
competition in defining relevant markets.6 Some courts have explicitly
considered the impact of downstream products in defining the upstream
input market,7 while others have examined demand substitution at the
input level with no explicit consideration of demand and costs
downstream.8
Relevant market definition is typically focused on demand-side
substitutability. In the case of intermediate goods, solely examining
demand substitutability of potentially competing inputs to the exclusion
of downstream market conditions can lead to an inaccurate relevant
product and geographic market definition.9 For example, firms
6. U.S. DEPT OF JUSTICE & FED. TRADE COMMN, HORIZONTAL MERGER
GUIDELINES § 4.1.3 (2010), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶
13,100, availa ble a t http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/guidelines/hmg-
2010.html [hereinafter 2010 MERGER GUIDELINES].
7. See, e.g., Brookins v. Int’l Mo tor Contest Ass’n, 219 F.3d 849, 853-54
(8th Cir. 2000) (rejecting a putative releva nt market of “IMCA-approved
transmissions for modified racing” based on competition for car races).
8. See, e.g., Arch Coa l, Inc., 329 F. Supp. 2d at 119-23 (considering
alternatives to Powder River Basin coal in defining the market but not
discussing costs of or demand for downstream electricity production).
9. See generally Richard S. H iggins & William F. Shughart II, Input Market
Definition Under DOJ Merger Guidelines, 4 REV. INDUS. ORG. 99
(1989); Paul Hofer, Mark Williams, & Lawrence Wu, The Economics of
Market Definition Analysis in Theory a nd in Pr actice, 2007 ASIA-PAC.
ANTITRUST REV. 10; Roman Inderst & Tommaso Valletti, Market
Manufacturing Input Markets
51
purchasing the input may have little ability to substitute to other inputs,
yet competition downstream at the final product stage may prohibit any
anticompetitive price increase of the input.
The demand for an input is what economists call a “derived” demand
because it is derived from the demand for the final product.10 Absent
demand for a final product, there would be no demand for the input.
Under the assumptions of perfect competition downstream and constant
returns to scale, the elasticity of demand for an input has long been
evaluated using conditions originally developed by Alfred Marshall11 and
later revised by John Hicks12 and commonly referred to by economists as
the “Hicks-Marshall” conditions of derived demand. These conditions
are well-established in economic literature.13 They state that, all else
being equal, the demand for an input is less elastic (i.e., less responsive
to price changes and, in the antitrust context, therefore more likely to
delineate a relevant antitrust market) when:
1) The elasticity of demand for the downstream product is low.14 If
demand for the downstream product is inelastic, any price
increase caused by a higher price of the input will lead to only a
small change in the quantity demanded of the downstream
product, and so is likely to lead to only a small change in the
quantity demanded of the input. Consideration of the elasticity
of demand for the downstream product can be very important for
defining a relevant market for an input.
Analysis in the Presence of Indirect Constraints and Captive Sales, 3 J.
COMPETITION L. & ECON. 203 (2007).
10. See, e.g., MARK HIRSCHEY, FUNDAMENTAL OF MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS
66 (9th ed. 2009).
11. ALFRED MARSHALL, PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS 518-38 (8th
ed.MacMillan & Co. 1923) (1890).
12. JOHN R. HICKS, THE THEORY OF WAGES 241-47 (St. Martin’s Press
1966).
13. See, e.g., P.R.G. LAYARD & A.A. WALTERS, MICRO-ECONOMIC THEORY
259-76 (1978) ; GEORGE J. STIGLER, THE THEORY OF PRICE 252-55 (4th
ed. 1987).
14. See, e.g., B.F. Goo drich Co., 110 F.T.C. 207, 282-83, 317 (1988)
(opinion of the commission) (discussing the importance of downstream
demand elasticity in determining competitive effects of a merger
upstream).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT