Regulation And Deregulation Of Electric And Gas Industries

Pages11-36
11
CHAPTER II
REGULATION AND DEREGULATION OF
ELECTRIC AND GAS INDUSTRIES
Over the last twenty years, both the gas and electric industries have
moved from a heavily regulated environment, dominated by monopoly
providers delivering a bundled product,11 to a more competitive
paradigm in which multiple suppliers compete to sell unbundled, or
partially unbundled, commodities and services. Beginning in the 1970s
with federal legislative efforts designed to encourage new suppliers, the
supply side of the gas industry has now been almost entirely deregulated,
and while electric supply has been substantially deregulated.
Deregulation has not taken hold as readily in the transmission and
distribution sectors of the industries, however, because these functions
still retain the characteristics of a natural monopoly. Indeed, ensuring
nondiscriminatory access to essential, monopoly facilities has been
critical toward allowing the competitive market to displace regulation of
energy supply. Accordingly, energy suppliers and customers will be
closely scrutinizing the activities of transmission owners, pipelines, and
their affiliates in the newly competitive markets and might seek recourse
under the antitrust laws if abusive practices occur.
This handbook focuses on the increasingly fertile ground for antitrust
actions as the electric and gas industries restructure.12 In order to
understand more fully the current state of those industries, this chapter
provides additional historical background on the advent of current
deregulation policies, the perceived regulatory failures underlying these
policies, and preliminary attempts to address those failures.
11. “Bundled products” or “bundled services” refer to the provision of gas or
electricity as a commodity, combined with the transportation and other
services necessary to support delivery of the commodity.
12 This discussion will necessarily touch only on the highlights of antitrust
law that are most relevant to energy issues. For a more comprehensive
discussion of the fundamental principles of antitrust law, see ABA
ANTITRUST SECTION, ANTITRUST LAW DEVELOPMENTS (5th ed. 2002)
(ALD V).
12 Energy Antitrust Handbook
A. Restructuring the Gas Industry
For much of the century, gas service was provided as a bundled
product, with monopoly pipelines purchasing gas from producers, then
transporting the gas for delivery as a bundled product to LDCs. Prior to
1938, when Congress passed the Natural Gas Act (NGA),13 interstate
pipelines generally were not subject to regulation. The NGA was
designed to fill this “regulatory gap” by providing for federal agency
oversight of interstate wholesale gas sales and interstate transportation.14
Under this regulatory structure, the Federal Power Commission (FPC)
(and later FERC) would set pipeline rates that were just and reasonable
and nondiscriminatory.15 In practice, rates generally were designed to
allow recovery of the pipeline’s cost of providing service, including a
return of and on invested capital.16
While the FPC was intended to protect consumers from unreasonable
prices charged by monopoly pipelines, finding an alternative regulated
pricing structure for gas supply also proved to be fraught with problems.
Initially, the FPC undertook regulation of gas production only for gas
produced by a pipeline or pipeline affiliate, leaving independent
producers unregulated.17 In 1954, however, the Supreme Court rejected
this approach, finding that the PFC was required to exert jurisdiction
over gas sales made by independent producers as well.18 The FPC first
attempted to regulate those producers as it had pipelines, using
13. 15 U.S.C. §§ 717-717w (1997 & Supp. 2002).
14. See, e.g., United Distrib. Cos. v. FERC, 88 F.3d 1105, 1122 (D.C. Cir.
1996) (noting the so-called “regulatory gap” derived from Supreme Court
decisions interpreting the Commerce Clause as precluding state
regulation of interstate transportation and wholesale sales) (citing
Arkansas Elec. Cooperative Corp. v. Arkansas Public Serv. Comm’n,
461 U.S. 375, 377-80 (1983)). This regulatory gap is fundamentally the
same as that described for the electric industry in Public Utilities
Comm’n v. Attleboro Steam & Elec. Co., 273 U.S. 83 (1927), see also
CHARLES F. PHILLIPS, THE REGULATION OF PUBLIC UTILITIES: THEORY
AND PRACTICE 697-98 (1993).
15. NGA § 4(a), 15 U.S.C. § 717c(a) (1997 & Supp. 2002)..
16. See Federal Power Comm’n v. Hope Natural Gas Co., 320 U.S. 591, 596,
605 (1944) (upholding FPC’s use of original cost basis for setting rates,
in that end result was a just and reasonable rate).
17. See Public Serv. Comm’n v. Mid-Louisiana Gas Co., 463 U.S. 319, 328
(1983).
18. Phillips Petroleum Co. v. Wisconsin, 347 U.S. 672 (1954).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT