Monopolization Issues

Pages167-203
167
CHAPTER IX
MONOPOLIZATION ISSUES
Energy utilities traditionally were viewed as natural monopolies, and
thus granted the exclusive right to serve a defined territory subject to
regulatory oversight by state utility commissions. So long as the utility
was subject to active state supervision, its conduct generally was immune
from antitrust scrutiny under the state action immunity doctrine.608
Deregulation, however, brings with it a corresponding loss of this
protective immunity. As deregulation progresses, claims of abuse of
monopoly power may become increasingly common, both as a means for
challenging efforts of traditional suppliers to retain or expand market
share, and for contesting new arrangements to market energy and energy
services.
A. Possession of Monopoly Power in the Relevant Market
Market shares often are used as a proxy or first screen to determine if
a party possesses market power.609 The precise market shares required
are a matter of some dispute: “While the Supreme Court has refused to
specify a minimum market share necessary to indicate a defendant has
monopoly power, lower courts generally require minimum market share
of between 70% and 80%.”610 A market share below 50 percent generally
is insufficient to establish market power.611 In regulated industries,
market share is not as good an indicator of market power as in other
608. See Parker v. Brown, 317 U.S. 341 (1943); Chapter IV, supra . So long as
the state continues to actively supervise the delivery of electricity,
identity of the “monopolist” will not have antitrust consequences. See
Columbia River People’s Utility District v. Portland General Electric
Co., 2000-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 72,920 (9th Cir. 2000); the Oregon PUC
approved a settlement of a condemnation action resulting in transfer of
property. The condemnation is restriction on competition. Only the name
of the monopolist changed.
609. See also discussion of market power in Chapter V.
610. Colorado Interstate Gas Co. v. Natural Gas Pipeline Co., 885 F.2d 683,
694 n.18 (10th Cir. 1989).
611. U.S. Anchor Mfg. v. Rule Indus., 7 F.3d 986, 1000 (11th Cir. 1993).
168 Energy Antitrust Handbook
industries, and may overstate the ability of a party to control prices and
reduce output.612
Market share is useful only as a first step in analyzing whether
market power exists. In determining the necessary market share, a court
will examine a series of market characteristics, including the size and
strength of competitors, barriers to entry, the degree of concentration,
profit levels, and whether the market share of the challenged party has
increased in recent times.613 The inaccuracies that result from the static
market share analysis can be overcome by looking at other factors
affecting the parties’ ability to collude or exercise market power. Market
shares must also be viewed in the context of fundamental changes
occurring in the structure of the relevant market.614 Where, for example,
the structure of the electricity or gas market is changing dramatically,
current market shares could overstate market power.
A number of factors complicate the determination of relevant
product and geographic markets for monopoly claims in today’s energy
industry. As a result, market definition issues likely will be contested
vigorously in such cases. One result of deregulation is that gas pipeline
and electric transmission grid operating functions that previously were
viewed as part of a single product market now may be considered
separate markets. Generation, transmission, and distribution functions,
which a single, vertically integrated utility formerly performed, now may
be unbundled. Companies that previously offered only natural gas or
electricity now may offer both. Previously regulated entities, directly or
through an affiliate, also may begin to offer nonregulated energy
services, including energy management programs, energy efficiency
equipment, electric system repair, home-appliance repair, environmental
services, and lightbulbs.
612. Consolidated Gas Co. v. City Gas Co., 880 F.2d 297, 300 (11th Cir.
1989), reinstated on reh’g, 912 F.2d 1262 (11th Cir. 1990) (en banc; per
curiam), vacated as moot, 499 U.S. 915 (1991).
613. Oahu Gas Serv. v. Pacific Resources, Inc., 838 F.2d 360, 366 (9th Cir.
1988).
614. See United States v. General Dynamics Corp., 415 U.S. 486, 501 (1974).
Chapter IX 169
Technological changes could ease entry into the electricity market,
for example, by creating new opportunities for self-generation or
cogeneration. New technology also may create the potential for
additional generation capacity even in an existing market.615
The unique characteristics of electricity make determining the
relevant market especially challenging. Electric energy cannot be stored.
The demand for electricity varies day by day as well as seasonally. Some
customers need reliability, others focus on lower prices. Some customers
need power at times of peak demand while others are able to purchase
off-peak.616 Therefore, product-market analysis will need to take into
account such factors as time, reliability, and interruptibility. The
continuous need to balance supply and demand in the electric industry
means that the ability to exploit market power can shift even during the
course of a single day and might make even half-hour-by-half-hour
product markets relevant.617 Innovations like time-of-day metering could
reduce transmission congestion and therefore market power.618
For geographic market determinations, a utility’s former service
territory is not necessarily the relevant market. Deregulation will allow
competitors from other states or territories to enter and serve that area.
As deregulation progresses, the issue of which entities potentially can or
do compete in a particular area will need to be continually revisited. For
example, greater transmission access can broaden the relevant
geographic market even if there is no new generation capacity.619
Markets might span several states, and might even be international to the
615. See, e.g., Comment of Staff of Bureau of Economics, Federal Trade
Commission, before Louisiana Public Service Commission Regarding
Market Structure, Market Power, Reliability and ISOs, Docket No. U-
21453 (May 15, 1998).
616. See Statement of Robert Pitofsky, Chairman, Federal Trade Comm’n,
Testimony before House Judiciary Comm. (June 4, 1997), available at
www.ftc.gov/os/1997/9706/electric.htm.
617. See, e.g., Comment of Staff of Bureau of Economics, Federal Trade
Comm’n, before FERC Inquiry Concerning Commission Policy On ISOs
(May 1, 1998).
618. See, e.g., Comment of Staff of Bureau of Economics, Federal Trade
Comm’n, before Public Service Commission of West Virginia,
Charleston, Case No. 98-0452-E-GT (July 15, 1998).
619. Id.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT