Financial Issues (Panel Transcript)

Pages241-279
241
CHAPTER X
FINANCIAL ISSUES (PANEL TRANSCRIPT)
Moderator
Dennis W. Carlton
University of Chicago, Chicago, IL
Panelists
Lawrence J. White
New York University, New York, NY
Thomas O. Barnett
Covington & Burling LLP, Washington, DC
MR. CARLTON: My name is Dennis Carlton. I‘m the moderator. I
am from the University of Chicago.
I am pleased to be the moderator of such a distinguished panel. We
have two panelists who are very well suited to talk about problems both
of the financial crisis and the interplay of the financial crisis with
antitrust.
We have Larry White, who is the Arthur Imperatore Professor of
Economics at NYU. In addition to being a highly regarded and highly
productive research scholar, Larry wears many hats, one of which is as a
former regulator. He sat on the Board of th e Federal Home Loan Bank
Board, and he also was one of my predecessors at the Department of
Justice, where he served as Chief Economist in the early 1980s.
The second panelist is a luminary in the antitrust world and
undoubtedly needs no introduction, so I will be short. He is currently the
chair of the antitrust practice at Covington & Burling. As everyone
undoubtedly knows, he is my former boss. He was the recent Assistant
Attorney General [of the Antitrust Division]. I can assure you it was a
delight to work under Tom. Not only did I learn a lot of law, but Tom
knows an incredible amount of economics. I learned he was a roommate
of one of my colleagues at the University of Chicago Business School.
I am going to start off with about 15 minutes or so of comments to
set the stage and then turn it over to Larry and Tom, each of whom will
speak for around 25 to 30 minutes.
During the Great Depression, from 19291933, real income fell by
30 percent, unemployment went from 3 percent to 25 percent, prices fell
by about 25 percent, and stocks went down by about 85 percent.
242 Competition as Public Policy
One of Milton Friedman‘s great contributions, together with Anna
Schwartz, was in studying t his period he noticed that the response of the
Federal Reserve made the Great Depression much worse; it was the
response of the economy to the initial shocks that were occurring that
actually made things pretty bad.
We are not in a Great Depression, but I wanted to follow the insight
of Friedman and Schwartz, which is to look at the r esponse to an initial
shock, a negative shock, and ask what can we learn from that? In
particular, we are in, or are coming out of, a financial crisis, and the
question is: how does our economy respond to the financial crisis?
My point is going to be a simple one. It is that, contrary to this
stream of criticism that we had too many markets, that markets didn‘t
work and we should get rid of them, I think just the opposite: we want to
have more markets working and we want to make them work better.
I am going to focus my remarks really on two points of law in
market creation, one of which has to do with bankruptcy law, and the
other having to do with the creation of organized exchanges.
Let me first turn to bankruptcy law. There is this notionand it
came up a little yesterdaythat when people hear that a company is
going bankrupt, they think that it‘s like getting blown up, that all its
assets are disappearing. Well, that‘s not necessarily what bankruptcy
means. The assets often stay in place; it‘s just their ownership that
changes.
Oftentimes when you read or listen t o commentators, they take the
first view of bankruptcy, ―You can‘t let a company go bankrupt because
that will destroy all its assets.‖ Sometimes that can occur, but in some of
the bankruptcies that we have been talking about and that have been in
the press, we are not really talking about assets being made completely
worthless.
If you focus on financial firms, they need to have their assets liquid,
they have to have access to those assets and they have to trade all the
time, every ten seconds or even faster. If you are a financial firm and
you are told, ―Hey, billions of dollars of your assets, don‘t worry, they‘re
secure, but you can‘t get them for a while; I‘ll tell you when you‘ll have
access to them‖—well, that could be the kiss of death.
In general, uncertainty about when a bankruptcy will be resolved, as
well as to the outcome of the bankruptcy, can have serious consequences
for all firms in the economy, whether a financial firm or not. By creating
this uncertainty, there is a huge gain to you in waiting before you do
anything else. So you wait because you are going to get more
information, and as you get more information, you‘ll have a b etter idea
Financia l Issues (Panel Tra nscript) 243
of what your future is going to look like; therefore, in financial terms, the
option value to waiting, to doing nothing, rises. From a macro point of
view, if everybody stops doing everything, or suspends many actions for
a while, then you have real trouble.
If you focus on financial firms, it is even worse. If I am a financial
firm, I want to trade constantly. If you tell me I don‘t have access to my
assets, then what am I supposed to do?
And then think of the following: suppose you are a financial fir m
and you hear that the investment bank where your accounts are may not
have access to its assets because they‘re tied up in some bankruptcy in
England. What do you say to yourself? You say: ―If my customers hear
that their assets that they‘ve put with my f irm may be tied up in some
bankruptcy proceeding in, say, London, they are going to try to take their
assets out.‖ So hedge funds, which have their funds held in investment
banks, are going to get nervous, and you‘re going to see a run on
investment banks as they try to pull their funds out.
That‘s kind of what we saw. That is what really spooked, in part, the
Fed. That‘s why you saw all of this rapid motion and rapid change to
make all these bank holding companies into banks and start guaranteeing
debt and the like.
So what is the solution? The solution is to make the Bankruptcy
Codes work much better and much faster. Maybe you want a special
term when financial firms are involved that explains how you can
rapidly, instantaneously, by the end of the day, resolve any issues
associated with bankruptcy that have to do with where your funds are or
who has access to them.
Although bankruptcy can impose costs on all types of firms, the cost
of delay for financial firms can be especially large. If we had been able
to make the Bankruptcy Code work much more quickly for them in times
of distress, we would have been able to eliminate some of these run-like
problems for investment banks.
Now, although the courts through the Bankruptcy Code are one way
to deal with this notion of bankruptcy, counter-party risk, and liquidity,
another way is the greater use of organized exchanges and
clearinghouses.
Let me just start out with an example. Suppose now I am no longer
an investment bank, I‘m a wheat farmer. So I‘m a wheat farmer and I
see my harvest is going to come in in two months. I sell my wheat to
someone who‘s a baker. So Joe here is a baker, he buys my wheat, we
set a price, and I‘m going to deliver it in two months to his factory. The
price is $1.00 a bushel.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT