Under pressure: Reputation, ratings, and inaccurate self‐reporting in the nursing home industry

AuthorAmanda Sharkey,Amandine Ody‐Brasier
Date01 October 2019
Published date01 October 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/smj.3063
RESEARCH ARTICLE
Under pressure: Reputation, ratings, and inaccurate
self-reporting in the nursing home industry
Amandine Ody-Brasier
1
| Amanda Sharkey
2
1
Yale University, School of Management,
New Haven, Connecticut
2
University of Chicago, Booth School of
Business, Chicago, Illinois
Correspondence
Amandine Ody-Brasier, Yale University,
School of Management, 165 Whitney
Avenue, New Haven, CT 06517.
Email: amandine.ody-brasier@yale.edu
Abstract
Research Summary:This paper examines firms' strategic
responses to reputational pressures in a critical healthcare
domainthe U.S. nursing home industry. We investigate
whether organizations improved in terms of care quality
following an exogenous change in the required number of
nursing hours associated with star-based ratings to which
nursing homes are subject. We show that although firms at
risk of losing a star tended to self-report higher staffing
levels after the policy change, these reported increases
were not associated with improvements in an important
patient outcomebedsores. These findings are consistent
with false reporting of staffing data, or insufficient or inef-
fective hiring practices. Although we cannot definitively
establish the existence of false reporting, supplementary
analyses offer little support for the latter two possibilities.
Managerial Summary:Third-party ratings systems often
stipulate that firms meet certain standards to attain a favor-
able evaluation. Firms must make strategic decisions about
whether and how to comply with these. This paper exam-
ines firms' strategic responses to changes in the required
number of nursing hours associated with star-based ratings
in the nursing home industry. Our results indicate that
firms at risk of losing a star responded by reporting
staffing increases. However, we find no concurrent
improvement in a patient outcome that previous research
suggests should change as a result of increased staffing.
We investigate whether the lack of improvement may be
due to insufficient or ineffective hiring, and find scant evi-
dence of either one. Although we lack direct evidence
Received: 17 May 2018 Revised: 15 May 2019 Accepted: 28 May 2019 Published on: 5 August 2019
DOI: 10.1002/smj.3063
Strat Mgmt J. 2019;40:15171544. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/smj © 2019 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. 1517
of false reporting, our findings suggest this as a strong
possibility.
KEYWORDS
healthcare, nursing homes, rating systems, reputation, response to
regulation
1|INTRODUCTION
Information asymmetries are endemic to markets for many types of products and services (Akerlof,
1970). In recent decades, a multitude of ratings, rankings, certification/labeling, and disclosure sys-
tems have arisen to mitigate such disparities between consumers and producers. These forms of
third-party evaluation involve the disclosure of novel information that sheds light on a firm' s standing
relative to others along valued dimensions, such as quality or environmental performance, thereby
contributing to organizational reputation (Espeland & Sauder, 2016; Lange, Lee, & Dai, 2011; Rao,
1994; Rindova, Williamson, Petkova, & Sever, 2005).
Research across a variety of empirical settings demonstrates that information provided by third-
party evaluators can, through the mechanism of reputation, shape consumer and investor choices
(e.g., Bowman & Bastedo, 2009; Gordon, Knock, & Neely, 2009; Lyon & Shimshack, 2015; Mere-
dith, 2004; Pope, 2009; Sauder & Lancaster, 2006). Moreover, scholars have argued that ratings,
rankings, and other third-party evaluationsbecause of their wide reach and perceived expert
statuscan drive more sudden and dramatic shifts in reputation than may have occurred in the past
(Espeland & Sauder, 2016; Rindova et al., 2005). Thus, ratings and other forms of public evaluation
represent an ever more consequential part of the environment in which firms make strategic
decisions.
In turn, policymakers and government officials have increasingly adopted ratings and other forms
of public evaluation, a strategy that Schneiberg and Bartley (2008) characterize as regulation by
information.When used as a policy tool, these forms of public evaluation are premised on the idea
that reputational incentivesin the form of consumer and investor responses to newly public
informationcan incentivize organizations to maintain or improve their performance on such other-
wise difficult-to-observe dimensions as quality, safety, and environmental compliance.
However, there are a range of strategic actions that firms might adopt in the face of such regula-
tion by information. On the one hand, some organizations have responded to ratings and rankings by
initiating changes that have led to substantial improvements (see, e.g., Jin & Leslie, 2003; Bennear &
Olmstead, 2008; Chatterji & Toffel, 2010; Sharkey & Bromley, 2015). Chatterji and Toffel (2010)
show, for example, that firms tend to reduce their emissions of toxic pollutants once their output
becomes subject to public ratings.
On the other hand, some organizations have responded by engaging in various forms of gaming
the system,which Espeland and Sauder (2007, p. 29) define broadly as manipulating the rules and
numbers in ways that are unconnected to, or even undermine, the motivation behind them.For
instance, medical facilities have chosen to admit relatively healthier patients, which improves the
mortality ratings that form a key basis of their ratings but does nothing to improve the treatment of
sick individuals (Dranove, Kessler, McClellan, & Satterthwaite, 2003). Additional types of gaming
1518 ODY-BRASIER AND SHARKEY

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT