Transactional hazards, institutional change, and capabilities: Integrating the theories of the firm

AuthorJorge Tarziján,Francisco Brahm
Date01 February 2014
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2094
Published date01 February 2014
Strategic Management Journal
Strat. Mgmt. J.,35: 224– 245 (2014)
Published online EarlyView 10 April 2013 in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com) DOI: 10.1002/smj.2094
Received 3 November 2010;Final revision received 27 November 2012
TRANSACTIONAL HAZARDS, INSTITUTIONAL
CHANGE, AND CAPABILITIES: INTEGRATING THE
THEORIES OF THE FIRM
FRANCISCO BRAHM and JORGE TARZIJ ´
AN*
School of Management, Pontificia Universidad Cat ´
olica de Chile, Santiago, Chile
Using a detailed dataset from the Chilean construction industry, we explorehow the predictions of
the transaction cost and capabilities theories interact to explain building contractors’ decisions
to ‘make or buy’ the specialty trade activities needed to complete a construction project. We
show that the contractor’s productive capabilities strongly mediate the relationship between
transaction hazards that originate from either temporal specificity or an exogenous change
in the subcontracting law and the vertical integration decision. The inclusion of differential
capabilities and its interaction with transactional hazards infuse contractors’ boundary choices
with systematic patterns of heterogeneity and contribute to the integration of these theoretical
perspectives. Our analysis corrects for the endogeneity of the capabilities variable and provides
a detailed assessment of the marginal effects in logit models. Copyright 2013 John Wiley &
Sons, Ltd.
INTRODUCTION
Researchers have sought to explain firm bound-
aries since the pioneering work of Coase (1937).
Scholars have theorized and empirically shown
(see Macher and Richman, 2008 for a review)
that transaction costs stemming from contracting
difficulties, particularly from inefficient ex-post
adaptation to high asset specificity (Williamson,
1979), from difficulties in measuring the qual-
ity of goods (Barzel, 1982) and from institu-
tional change enacted through variations in law
and regulation (Williamson, 2000), drive the
comparative assessment of market versus firm
governance.
In parallel, the development of the ‘capabili-
ties’ theory of firm boundaries, which maintains
Keywords: make or buy; transaction costs; capabilities;
institutional change; interaction effects
*Correspondence to: Jorge Tarzij´
an, School of Manage-
ment, Pontificia Universidad Cat´
olica de Chile, Avda. Vicu˜
na
Mackenna, Macul, Santiago, Chile. E-mail: jtarzija@uc.cl
Copyright 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
that firms will vertically integrate the transactions
for which they have stronger productive capabil-
ities than their suppliers (Argyres, 1996; Jaco-
bides and Winter, 2005), suggests that the differ-
ential in capabilities across firms may complement
the generic prescription derived from the char-
acteristics of the transaction itself , such as its
specificity, its institutional setting, and its measur-
ability. As such, the inclusion of capability differ-
entials among firms has the potential to provide a
more nuanced and comprehensive account of firm
boundaries, permitting the analysis of the hetero-
geneity of firm boundaries and the evolving rela-
tionship between capabilities and transaction costs
(Argyres et al., 2012).
The current article contributes to the existing
empirical research that seeks to fulfill the poten-
tial for integrating the roles of transaction costs
and firm capabilities into assessments of firm
boundaries (Fabrizio, 2012; Mayer and Salomon,
2006). Following Williamson (1999), we empir-
ically explore how the predictions of these the-
ories interact to explain the choice of Chilean
Integrating Theories of Firm Boundaries 225
building contractors either to subcontract specialty
trade activities (e.g., molding, plumbing, or heat-
ing) or to perform these activities internally. We
show that all of the transactional hazards exam-
ined, including the hazards created by ‘temporal
specificity’ (Masten, Meehan, and Snyder, 1991)
and the hazards produced by an exogenous change
in the subcontracting law that increases transac-
tion costs, are associated with increased vertical
integration. More importantly, however, we illus-
trate how a contractor’s productive capabilities in
specialty trade activities strongly mediate the rela-
tionship between transaction hazards and integra-
tion, acting as a shift parameter. A contractor with
strong productive capabilities can better counter-
act the impact of the increased transaction hazards
detailed above.
To reach this conclusion, our analysis identifies
the capabilities’ marginal effects in logit models,
an aspect that is almost absent from previous
research studies that use these models (e.g., Mayer
and Salomon, 2006), and illustrates how the
marginal effects differ depending on the ex-ante
likelihood of integration of boundary choices.
We also make three additional contributions to
the firm boundaries literature. First, we provide
evidence of boundary choices for the construc-
tion industry, an industry that has been mostly
neglected in previously published studies that
address the boundaries of firms. Second, we pro-
vide additional evidence for a distinct type of
specificity; namely, ‘temporal specificity,’ which
has received relatively little empirical attention
since its introduction by Masten et al. (1991).1
Finally, we argue that capability heterogeneity
may also be linked to prior governance choices
in industries such as construction (Argyres and
Zenger, 2012).
This article is divided into six sections. Follow-
ing this introduction, the second section presents
this study’s empirical setting, and the third section
develops its theories and hypotheses. The fourth
section provides the database and variable mea-
surements used for this investigation, and the
fifth section presents its econometric model and
main results, as well as the discussion of these
results. Finally, the sixth section provides our
conclusions.
1Some of the notable exceptions are the empirical studies by
Nickerson and Silverman (2003a, 2003b), which document the
presence of temporal specificity in trucking.
EMPIRICAL SETTING
We analyze the different hypotheses of this study
within the context of the construction industry.
This industry is important (it accounts for 8– 10%
of the GDP in many countries; see Gordon,
1992) and represents an ideal setting for research
on governance because construction projects are
long-lived, nonstandardized, and require coop-
eration between specialized project constituents,
all of which lead to complex relations between
firms and contractual intensity and incompleteness
(Puddicombe, 2009; Winch, 2001). However, we
know of only three studies that have empirically
explored the vertical integration of this industry
Eccles (1981) and Gonzalez-Diaz, Arru˜
nada, and
Fern´
andez (1998, 2000). We seek to add to this
literature by studying the ‘make or buy’ decision
that building contractors must make for eight dis-
tinct specialty trade activities: (1) building and
installing the metallic structure, (2) building the
formwork, (3) installing the electrical services,
(4) installing the plumbing and water services,
(5) installing the heating and cooling systems, (6)
building and installing the windows, (7) painting,
and (8) building and installing the furnishings and
the appliances. These activities account for a large
proportion of the total number of activities in typi-
cal construction projects.2For each of these activ-
ities, the contractor must decide whether to rely
on external subcontractors or to execute the task
directly.
Our units of analysis are the specialty trade
activities within projects. A building contractor
may be in charge of different projects. Each project
generally has an independent manager, workers,
designers, and geographical location. The con-
tractor may make different governance decisions
regarding each of the activities to be performed
in the projects. In this setting, ‘to buy’ implies
using subcontractors (also known as ‘specialty
trades contractors’). These subcontractors are
typically specialized in a particular activity,
with little diversification of their abilities among
2For example, Riley et al. (2005) indicated that the construction
activities (3), (4), and (5) account for 40– 50% of the total
construction costs in industrial, educational and health projects
and for 20– 30% of the total costs in commercial and housing
complex projects. Activities (1) and (7) are typically expensive,
especially in housing and residential building projects. All in all,
the activities we specified capture approximately 50% or more
of project costs.
Copyright 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,35: 224– 245 (2014)
DOI: 10.1002/smj

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT