The Structure of the Permanent Job Wage Premium: Evidence from Europe

Published date01 January 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/irel.12129
AuthorLawrence M. Kahn
Date01 January 2016
The Structure of the Permanent Job Wage
Premium: Evidence from Europe*
LAWRENCE M. KAHN
Using individual longitudinal European Community Household Panel data for
thirteen countries during 19952001 and xed-effects models, I nd for men, the
permanent job wage premium is higher for younger workers and those who were
noncitizens or foreign born; for women, the premium is higher for young work-
ers, short-tenure workers, and those who were noncitizens or foreign born. Thus,
the gain to permanent employment is higher for those with less experience in the
domestic labor market.
Introduction
A considerable volume of economic research has been devoted over the last
two decades to explaining and suggesting remedies for the stubbornly high
unemployment rates in a number of European countries. Among the suggested
policy remedies for reducing joblessness is the relaxation of systems of
employment protection by allowing rms greater freedom to create temporary
jobs. Such dual employment systems produce barriers into the protected, per-
manent job sector, because rms may be reluctant to create permanent jobs in
the presence of high ring costs. Moreover, the bargaining power of insiders
in the protected sector is likely to produce a pay gap relative to those in tem-
porary jobs, because the rm must pay ring costs if it decides to discharge
workers (Blanchard and Landier 2002; Boeri 2011; Booth, Francesconi, and
Frank 2002; Kahn 2007, 2012; Stancanelli 2002). Also, previous research has
found that the young, immigrants, and women are disproportionately concen-
trated in temporary jobs, which are sometimes seen as part of a process lead-
ing to labor-market dualism, due to the lower pay in temporary jobs and
barriers to entering permanent jobs (Kahn 2007).
While previous research on temporary and permanent employment outcomes
treats the temporary sector in the aggregate, some workers may still accumulate
*The authorsafliation is Cornell University, Ithaca, New York. Email: lmk12@cornell.edu.
This paper uses European Community Household Panel data (Users Database, waves 1-8, version of
December 2003), supplied courtesy of the European Commission, Eurostat. Data are obtainable by applica-
tion to Eurostat, which has no responsibility for the results and conclusions of this paper.
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS, Vol. 55, No. 1 (January 2016). ©2015 Regents of the University of California
Published by Wiley Periodicals, Inc., 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA, and 9600 Garsington
Road, Oxford, OX4 2DQ, UK.
149
training and valuable experience in temporary jobs, even if this is less extensive
than in permanent jobs. If so, then temporary jobs may themselves represent
less of a dead end in the labor market than otherwise imagined. Moreover, we
might expect different types of workers to experience different gains upon
obtaining a permanent job, depending on their experience while employed in a
temporary job. This heterogeneity in the wage gains for permanent employment
implies that the dual employment system can indirectly affect wage inequality
even beyond the average pay gap between permanent and temporary jobs.
In this paper, I use European Community Household Panel data (ECHP) to
investigate the premium workers command in permanent jobs relative to tem-
porary jobs across thirteen European countries: Austria, Belgium, Denmark,
Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, the Netherlands, Portugal,
Spain, and the United Kingdom. A basic framework to understand this issue
comes from Blanchard and Landiers (2002) research, in which it is assumed
that rms start workers in temporary jobs. Then as the expiration of the job
approaches, the rm must decide whether to promote the worker into a perma-
nent job or whether to start over with a new match in a temporary job. In the
presence of higher ring costs for permanent jobs relative to temporary jobs,
rms will be reluctant to make such promotions unless warranted by the eco-
nomic circumstances of the rm. Once promoted, workers are able to appropri-
ate some of the ring costs, since these raise the value of continuing the
employment match once the worker is promoted. Thus, an important determi-
nant of the wage premium in a permanent job is the value of the match rela-
tive to breaking it up and starting over with a temporary employee.
I hypothesize that before being promoted into a permanent job, inexperienced
workers must receive training in the temporary job for which they have been
hired. In equilibrium, their starting wages in the temporary job will be below the
level of starting wages for experienced, trained workers starting a temporary job.
After they have been trained, the rm may receive a productivity shock, which
will determine whether it will promote the workers. By this time, experienced
and inexperienced workers will each be trained and thus will be treated similarly
by the rm. Because of the wage discount at the beginning of the temporary job
for less experienced workers, the wage gain conditional on promotion to a per-
manent job will be greater for them. We observe a higher incidence of permanent
employment among more experienced workers because they have had more
opportunities to be in rms that receive a favorable productivity shock, and the
exit probability from permanent jobs is relatively low.
I test the prediction that the permanent job wage premium falls as labor-
market experience rises, using longitudinal data from the ECHP. Taking into
account individual xed effects, I nd that among men the wage premium for
a permanent versus temporary job is indeed higher for younger workers and
150 / LAWRENCE M. KAHN

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT