The interests of white‐collar workers and their representation in the German manufacturing sector: new initiatives, opportunity structures, framing and resources

Date01 July 2016
Published date01 July 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/irj.12141
AuthorThomas Haipeter
The interests of white-collar workers and
their representation in the German
manufacturing sector: new initiatives,
opportunity structures, framing and
resources
Thomas Haipeter
ABSTRACT
In the German manufacturing sector, white-collar workers have outpaced blue-collar
workers in numbers. Therefore, unions and works councils have launched initiatives
to attract, mobilise and organise white-collar workers. The analysis is drawing on a
conceptual framework that looks at the opportunity structures, framing processes
and resources of the initiatives.
1 INTRODUCTION: THE WHITE-COLLAR WORKER PROBLEM
This article is about new forms of interest representation that works councils and
trade unions have developed in recent years in German manufacturing industries in
order to attract, mobilise and organise white-collar workers. White-collar workers
have shown themselves to be a quite distinctive group of workers in many advanced
economies. It has been well known for decades that the work-related interests of
white-collar workers differ from those of blue-collar workers with respect to career
advancement, their relationships with superiors and their lack of working class
consciousness (Boltanski, 1987; Lockwood, 1958; Mills, 1951). These particularities
have been explained by their positions in the occupational hierarchies, by
differences between ofce and factory work or by ideological inuences in the sense
of false consciousness (for a summary, refer to Schmidt, 2015). In Germany, in
contrast to other countries, these differences were also based on the legal entitlements
to privileged social benets and the protection such as sick pay or higher pensions
that white-collar employees enjoyed, including a formal difference between hourly
wagesLöhnefor blue-collar workers and monthly salariesGehälterfor
white-collar workers that were laid down in separate collective bargaining agreements
(Kocka, 1981). Although the privileges and institutional differentiations between the
two groups of wage earners have been abolished in recent decades, the last being the
separate agreements for wages and salaries, which have been replaced by unitary
Thomas Haipeter, Institute Work, Skills and Training, Faculty of Social Sciences, University of
Duisburg-Essen, Lotharstraße 65, LE, 47057 Duisburg, Germany. Correspondence should be addressed
to Prof. Dr. Thomas Haipeter, Institute Work, Skills and Training, Faculty of Social Sciences,
University of Duisburg-Essen, Lotharstraße 65, LE, 47057 Duisburg, Germany email: thomas.
haipeter@uni-due.de
Industrial Relations Journal 47:4, 304321
ISSN 0019-8692
© 2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
agreements in many industries, the differences in interests have not narrowed, as more
recent studies show (Hoose et al., 2009; Kotthoff, 1997; Kudera et al., 1983). The
individualistic features of white-collar workersinterests seem to make them much
less susceptible to collective interest representation and aggregation than demands
for higher wages or shorter working times. Indeed, as research has shown, white-
collar workers are in the habit of pursuing their interests in an individual fashion by
talking to their superiors and not by contacting works councils or unions and asking
them to act on their behalf (Boes and Kämpf, 2010; Heidenreich and Töpsch, 1998;
Kotthoff, 1997).
This clearly creates a dilemma for works councils and trade unions. On one hand,
the interests of white-collar workers are hard to organise and the unions have their
strongholds traditionally among the rank and les of the blue-collar workers. On
the other hand, white-collar workers are becoming an increasingly important part
of the manufacturing workforce. Among the reasons for this long-term trend are
ongoing rationalisation in the blue-collar areas and the expansion of highly skilled
white-collar work in research and development, especially in the automotive industry
(Jürgens and Meissner, 2005). In 2011, half of the workers in the German
manufacturing sector were white-collar workers (Figure 1). In 2009 and 2010, the
share of white-collar workers was even greater than that of blue-collars, many of
whom, both temporary and permanent, were made redundant during the nancial
crisis, whereas companies were keen to retain their white-collar employees.
The gures show that unions that continue to put their efforts into representing
blue-collar workers are in danger of becoming fractal organisations in the future
(Dörre, 2011), representing only a minority of workers in their organisational sphere.
Moreover, white-collar workers have considerable structural power (Wright, 2000;
Silver, 2003) that increases with hierarchical position and/or skill level and which
works councils and unions can usefully exploit by soliciting their votes in works
council elections, commissioning them as expert advisers or consultants or recruiting
them as union members willing to strike.
Figure 1: Shares of blue and white-collar workers in the manufacturing sector, 19992011
(Socio-Economic Panel, own calculations)
305Interest representation and white-collar initiatives
© 2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT