The Impact of Living‐Wage Ordinances on Urban Crime

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/irel.12065
AuthorThomas Holman,John V. Pepper,Jose Fernandez
Published date01 July 2014
Date01 July 2014
The Impact of Living-Wage Ordinances on
Urban Crime
*
JOSE FERNANDEZ, THOMAS HOLMAN, and JOHN V. PEPPER
We examine the impact of living wages on crime. Past research has found that
living wages appear to increase unemployment while providing greater returns to
market work. The impact on crime, therefore, is unclear. Using data on annual
crime rates for large cities in the United States, we nd that living-wage ordi-
nances are associated with notable reductions in property-related crime and no
discernable impact on nonproperty crimes.
Introduction
OVER THE PAST 15 YEARS,A NUMBER OF CITY GOVERNMENTS HAVE ADOPTED
living-wage ordinances mandating wage oors exceeding the federal minimum
wage for certain classes of workers. These oors have been found to impact
the labor market for low-skilled workers, leading to fairly substantial increases
in expected wages and a small but statistically signicant reduction in employ-
ment (Campolieti, Fang, and Gunderson 2005; Neumark and Adams 2003b).
To the extent that these wage oors impact the labor market of the low
skilled, they might also affect nonlabor-market behaviors such as crime. In
this paper, we examine the unintended impact of living-wage ordinances on
crime.
In the standard neo-classical model, the opportunity cost of working in
the legal sector may inuence the propensity to commit crime (Becker
*The authorsafliations are, respectively, Department of Economics, University of Louisville, Louisville,
Kentucky Email: jose.fernandez@louisville.edu; San Francisco, California Email: thomas.t.hol-
man@gmail.com; Department of Economics, University of Virginia, Charlottesville, Virginia Email: jvpep-
per@virginia.edu
JEL: I18, H73, R50.
*The authors thank Scott Adams for providing data on living wage ordinances through 2002. Parts of the
crime data used in this paper were assembled by Rob Fornango, and made available to the authors by the
Committee on Law and Justice. The authors remain solely responsible for how the data have been used and
interpreted. Peppers research was supported in part by the Bankard Fund for Political Economy. They
would also like to thank the editor and the anonymous referees as well as the participants of the Midwest
Economic Association Conference (Cleveland, OH) for their helpful comments.
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS, Vol. 53, No. 3 (July 2014). ©2014 Regents of the University of California
Published by Wiley Periodicals, Inc., 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA, and 9600 Garsington
Road, Oxford, OX4 2DQ, UK.
478
1968; Levitt 1997). These ideas, in fact, are supported in the existing empir-
ical literature, which reveals a modest effect of unemployment and a some-
what more pronounced and lasting effect of wages on pecuniary crimes
(see, for examples, Grogger 1998; Freeman 1999; Gould, Weinberg, and
Mustard 2002; Lin 2008). This model, however, does not lead to a qualita-
tive prediction about the impact of wage oors on crime. Rather, by simul-
taneously increasing the returns to employment and the likelihood of
unemployment, theoretical predictions about the impact of living-wage ordi-
nances on crime are ambiguous. An increase in wages among the working
low skilled might be expected to decrease crime, yet the associated decrease
in employment might lead to an increase in crime. Given that living-wage
ordinances are found to have only a small negative impact on employment
but a much more pronounced positive effect on wages, one might reason-
ably speculate that these ordinances lead to a reduction in crime. Ultimately,
however, this is an empirical question that has not yet been addressed in
the literature.
To resolve this ambiguity, we use panel data on annual city-level crime
rates and living-wage ordinances from 19902010. For each city-year, we
observe the rates of different types of property and violent crimes, the mini-
mum and the living wage, and a detailed set of covariates. Given these data,
the basic empirical approach compares crime rates in cities before and after
the adoption of living-wage laws, as well as crime rates between cities that did
and did not adopt living-wage ordinances.
As with all such studies, a primary concern is that living-wage
ordinances may not be exogenous; living wages may be adopted or chan-
ged in response to factors that are unobserved to the econometrician but
are arguably associated with crime. For example, local labor market condi-
tions, the scal stability of local governments, and social services provided
by local governments may all be associated with living-wage provisions
and crime.
To account for the nonrandom adoption of living-wage laws, we use several
nested approaches. First, at the most basic level, we estimate models with a
rich set of covariates accounting for city/county- and state-level socioeconomic
and criminal justice variables that might confound inferences. Likewise, we
exploit the panel nature of the data by incorporating both city and time xed
effects, and city-specic linear and quadratic time trends.
1
Second, in addition
to presenting results for the full sample of cities, we also restrict the analysis
to cities that had a formal living-wage campaign, some of which passed and
1
Adams and Neumark (2005a, 2005b, 2005c) in their work examining the impact of living wages on
employment and earnings also consider city-specic linear time trends.
Living-Wage Ordinances and Urban Crime / 479

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT