Supplier evolution in global value chains and the new brand game from an attention‐based view

Date01 August 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/gsj.1381
AuthorChristian Lechner,Gaël Gueguen,Simone Guercini,Gianni Lorenzoni
Published date01 August 2020
SPECIAL ISSUE ARTICLE
Supplier evolution in global value chains and
the new brand game from an attention-
based view
Christian Lechner
1
| Gianni Lorenzoni
2,3
| Simone Guercini
4
|
Gaël Gueguen
5
1
School of Economics and Management, Free University of Bolzano, Bolzano, Italy
2
Department of Management, University of Bologna, Bologna, Italy
3
Cass Business School, City University London, London, UK
4
Department of Economics and Management (DIESEI), University of Florence, Florence, Italy
5
Management Research Centre, Entrepreneurship and Strategy, Toulouse Business School, Toulouse Cedex 7, France
Correspondence
Christian Lechner, School of Economics
and Management, Free University of
Bolzano, Piazza Università 1, 39100
Bolzano, Italy.
Email: christian.lechner@unibz.it
Funding information
University of Bologna (Alma Idea
Funding); Open Access Publishing Fund
of the Free University of Bozen-Bolzano
Abstract
Research Summary: Suppliers from emerging econo-
mies have been particularly active in acquiring brands
from advanced economies. We analyze changes in the
global value chain (GVC) of the sports shoe industry
and show how hollowing out the asset bases of brand-
holding firms through increasing outsourcing has
enabled the emergence of rising power firms, as well as
a new brand game and a market for brands. These
developments in the GVC might be a future challenge
for traditional brand-holding lead firms. We show that
managers focused on branding and distribution issues
were myopic towards the strategic initiatives of suppliers.
Managers need to pay attention to the potential long-
term consequences of outsourcing and offshoring activi-
ties, as suppliers could become competitors or acquirers
of their order-giving firms, leading to the question: Are
we approaching a state of dual GVC leadership, or do
lead firms risk being kicked out by their suppliers?
Received: 15 February 2018 Revised: 28 February 2020 Accepted: 10 March 2020
DOI: 10.1002/gsj.1381
This is an open access article under the terms of the Creative Commons AttributionNonCommercialNoDerivs License, which permits
use and distribution in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited, the use is noncommercial and no modifications or
adaptations are made.
© 2020 The Authors. Global Strategy Journal published by John Wiley & Sons Ltd on behalf of Strategic Management Society
520 Global Strategy Journal. 2020;10:520555.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/gsj
Managerial Summary: We explore the emergence of
rising power firms from the peripheries of GVCs. An
increasing number of major brand-holding companies
from traditionally industrial ized economies have been
acquired by suppliers from newl y industrialized econo-
mies due to some fundament al changes. First, the
emergence of a market for brands m akes brands more
volatile. Second, continuous outsourcing and hollowing-
out of the lead firm's asset base has reduced their ability
to control the GVC. Through a longitudinal case study
analysis, by adopting an attention-based view, we inves-
tigate the behavior of the traditional lead firms. Lead
firms were not only myopic to the activities of their sup-
pliers, but their focus on downstream activities created
increasing opportunity spaces upstream for rising power
firms while weakening the defense capacity of brands.
KEYWORDS
attention-based view, global value chains, lead firm, market for
brands, rising power suppliers, supplier evolution
1|INTRODUCTION
An increasing number of major brands from established industrialized economies have been
acquired by suppliers based in emerging economies. Those suppliers have been participating for
years in global value chains (GVCs). The GVC view concerns all activities necessary to bring a
specific product from conception to end use (Gereffi & Fernandez-Stark, 2011). GVCs are
orchestrated by a lead firm (Mudambi & Venzin, 2010), and the lead firm strategically directs
the activities of the value chain (Jarillo, 1993; Lorenzoni & Baden-Fuller, 1995). Two generic
GVCs derive from the typology of the lead firm: producer-driven and buyer-driven (Gereffi,
2001). In a producer-driven GVC, firms with a high degree of production activity are the lead
firms; in a buyer-driven GVC, production appears to be dispensable, and the lead firms are the
brand-holding firms (Pananond, 2013). We view a supplier acquiring the brand of a lead firm as
an extreme case of rising power firms from the periphery (Lee & Gereffi, 2015), illustrating posi-
tion shifts in GVCs through supplier upgrading (Pananond, 2013, 2016). The emergence of giant
suppliers is indeed surprising, considering the fact that the end of immense manufacturing
facilities has been declared for decades (Appelbaum, 2008). These rising power firms aim at
challenging the position of the lead firm (Yamin & Sinkovics, 2015). As the study of rising
power suppliers has been neglected (Appelbaum, 2008), these changes call for more attention to
global GVC management (Sako & Zylberberg, 2019).
Participation in GVCs is seen as a fundamental precondition for supplier upgrading because
GVCs are where learning happens through interaction with (initially) more advanced actors
(Gereffi, 2001). Mere participation does not automatically lead to upgrading (Humphrey &
LECHNER ET AL.521
Schmitz, 2001). On one hand, the degree of upgrading depends on the firm's position within the
GVC (first tier, second tier, etc.), which is essentially its proximity to the lead firm; on the other
hand, the governance structure of the GVC determines how and if a supplier will upgrade. The
literature on governance structures assumes that the lead firm controls authority and power
in the GVC. This kind of control would make supplier upgrading unlikely (Sako & Zylberberg,
2019). Indeed, studies have suggested that lead firms place limits on the suppliers' development
by governing relationships in the GVC, thus creating a glass ceiling for suppliers (McDermott &
Corredoira, 2010).
This view, however, might be a little short-sighted. For instance, in the mobile phone indus-
try, four of the top five firms in terms of sales are former suppliers, whereas Apple is the only
firm without a production base. Moreover, the operating profits of advanced suppliers have
been consistently higher, but brand control has been viewed as essential (Dedrick, Kraemer, &
Linden, 2011).
1
More fundamental changes over time might be underway. First, there is a new
brand gameat play. Our analysis of the sports shoe industry suggests that outsourcing activi-
ties of brand-holding firms has, in the first place, created GVC and, in the second place, a mar-
ket for brands. Research suggests that, starting from the 1980s, there has been strong growth in
brand trading (Lechner, Lorenzoni, & Tundis, 2016): The argument brought forward is that a
market for brands can emerge if brands can be somehow disembodied from upstream activities,
such as manufacturing and design, as is typical in buyer-driven GVCs. Data collected specifi-
cally in the sports shoe industry shows that suppliers are highly active in this new brand trading
game (Lechner, Lorenzoni, & Tundis, 2018).
2
Over the decade between 2006 and 2015, suppliers
accounted for 24% of all brand acquisitions or more than 100 transactions; investors, who were
buying brands as tradable assets for future resale, for 23%, and distributors for 13%; however,
the top 10 brand holding firms (in terms of sales) only account for about 5% (Lechner
et al., 2018).
Overall, brands are increasingly being traded, and suppliers appear to be most active in
acquiring brands from original brand holders. The substantial market for brands and therefore
the frequent trading of brands, then makes defending the brand more difficult. Indeed, in the
sports shoe industry, spending in brands is relatively high, including advertising and sponsoring
activities, as brand-holding firms tend to have fewer types of differentiating strategic assets
(Merk, 2004). Besides the top two firms in this industry, where advertising spending has
increased proportionally with sales, most of the other firms saw their brand spending over-
proportionally increasing throughout the previous decade, as illustrated in Table 1. High brand
volatility through a vibrant market for brands and increasing brand spending means that a spe-
cific brand matters less.
Second, lead firms' control, and thus their power in the GVC, has been declining, lead-
ing to the emergence of rising power firms (Lee & Gereffi, 2015). To illustrate here, we
only would like to anticipate one example (supplier evolution will be discussed in more
detail in the section on the case setting as well as in the Appendix). Adidas, one of the
main footwear sports brands, announced that it would close down their Speed Factories in
Germany and the United States by the end of 2019, which had opened only in 2017. These
speed factories were small, highly automated factories that allowed for smaller batches of
specialized shoes to be produced very quickly. The speed factories will be handed over to
one of their first tier suppliers, since that is where institutional knowledge resides. Adidas
considered these factories to be a great learning experience, but the home reshoring
attempt was ultimately a failure (Toffel, McNeely, & Preble, 2019). Third, rising power sup-
pliers started to occupy lower segments that were left overby the lead firms in the end
522 LECHNER ET AL.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT