Subprime governance: Agency costs in vertically integrated banks and the 2008 mortgage crisis

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2481
AuthorClaudine Gartenberg,Lamar Pierce
Published date01 February 2017
Date01 February 2017
Strategic Management Journal
Strat. Mgmt. J.,38: 300–321 (2017)
Published online EarlyView 12 February 2016 in WileyOnline Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com) DOI: 10.1002/smj.2481
Received 11 May 2015;Final revision received14 October 2015
SUBPRIME GOVERNANCE: AGENCY COSTS IN
VERTICALLY INTEGRATED BANKS AND THE 2008
MORTGAGE CRISIS
CLAUDINE GARTENBERG1*and LAMAR PIERCE2
1Management and Organizations, NYU Stern School of Business, New York, New
York, U.S.A.
2Olin Business School, Washington University in St. Louis, St. Louis, Missouri,
U.S.A.
Research summary: This study uses the 2008 mortgage crisis to demonstrate how the relationship
between vertical integration and performance crucially depends on corporate governance. Prior
research has argued that the vertical integration of mortgage origination and securitization
aligned divisional incentives and improved lending quality. We show that vertical integration
improved loan performance only in those rms with strong corporate governance and that this
performance-integration relationship strongly decreases and actually reverses as governance
quality decreases. We interpret these ndings as suggesting that the additional control afforded
by vertical integration can, in the hands of poorly monitored managers,offset gains from aligned
divisional incentives. These ndings support the view that corporate governance inuences the
strategic outcomes of a rm, in our case, by inuencing the effectiveness of boundary decisions.
Managerial summary: One of the unanswered questions of the 2008 mortgage crisis is why
some rms produced toxic mortgages and others did not. Many have argued that vertically
integrated banks—banks that both originated and securitized mortgages —had incentives to
monitor themselves and thereby avoid overaggressive lending and outright fraud. Yet many
of the worst lenders, such as Washington Mutual and New Century Financial, were in fact
integrated. This study shows that the behavior of these rms critically depended on their corporate
governance. We nd that poorly monitored executives used their additional control over the
integrated businesses to issue low quality loans that supported short-term growth. Our results
suggest that governance is a crucial prerequisitefor nancial services, particularly for rms whose
managers control multiple, interrelatedbusinesses. Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
INTRODUCTION
In this article, we provide evidence that the rela-
tionship between vertical integration and perfor-
mance depends on corporate governance. We study
this role of governance in the context of one
Keywords: vertical integration; corporate governance;
transaction cost economics; mortgage securitization;
boundaries of the rm
*Correspondence to: Claudine Gartenberg, 40 West 4th Street,
Tisch 709 New York, NY 10012, U.S.A. E-mail: cgartenb@
stern.nyu.edu
Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
of the most important market failures in recent
history— the 2008 American housing crisis. Recent
research in corporate nance on the underlying
causes of the crisis has argued that the vertical
integration of mortgage origination and securiti-
zation aligned divisional incentives, and thereby
helped banks avoid severe lending quality problems
(Demiroglu and James, 2012; Purnanandam, 2011).
Yet, many of the worst performing lenders, such as
Washington Mutual, Wachovia, and New Century
Financial, were in fact integrated, having pursued
deliberate strategies to control the vertical chain.
These lenders subsequently collapsed spectacularly
Agency Costs in Vertically Integrated Banks and the 2008 Mortgage Crisis 301
once the housing market weakened in 2008. What
explains the poor performance by integrated rms?
We propose that weak corporate governance in
vertically integrated banks led to agency prob-
lems of the sort that are particularly pronounced
in information-intensive industries. Within these
rms, “soft” information— such as intangible bor-
rower risk factors— is passed internally between
divisions and is difcult for the outside market
to validate (Gartenberg, 2014; Pierce, 2012). A
deep literature in strategy and economics shows
that such information asymmetry makes aspects of
corporate governance such as executive compensa-
tion (Finkelstein and Hambrick, 1988; Harris and
Bromiley, 2007; Jensen and Murphy, 1990; Sanders
and Hambrick, 2007), board structure (Dalton et al.,
1998; Johnson, Hoskisson, and Hitt, 1993; West-
phal and Fredrickson, 2001), and investor compo-
sition (Hoskisson et al., 2002; Schnatterly, Shaw,
and Jennings, 2008) crucial for aligning man-
agerial actions with shareholder interests. With-
out sufcient monitoring by boards (Baysinger and
Hoskisson, 1990) or outside investors (Bushee,
1998; Thomsen and Pedersen, 2000), top managers
have wide discretion to either shirk responsibilities
or implement strategy and policies that enable them
to achieve compensation, status, and other personal
goals at the expense of shareholder value.
Vertical integration extends top managers’
span of control over the supply chain. Given this
increased control, we propose that weak corporate
governance allows two costly types of agency prob-
lems. First, managers can pursue self-interested
goals by distorting the activities of each division
as well as the terms of exchange and information
passed between them. Indeed, while recent work
suggests that vertical integration did in fact align
divisional incentives in banks (Demiroglu and
James, 2012), this alignment under weak gover-
nance may have served managerial rent-seeking
rather than shareholder value. Weak corporate gov-
ernance enables the top management team to struc-
ture compensation systems, reporting hierarchies,
and culture within the organization to support the
managers’ goals of myopic growth and excessive
risk (Werner, Tosi, and Gomez-Mejia, 2005). In this
way, the increased coordination, shared language,
and knowledge that is argued to produce benets by
some organizational scholars (Grant, 1996; Kogut
and Zander, 1992; Macher, 2006; Nahapiet and
Ghoshal, 1998), can produce the value-destroying
distortion highlighted by other scholars (Bidwell,
2012; Eccles and White, 1988; Nickerson and
Zenger, 2004; Osterloh and Frey, 2000).
Second, weak governance can also allow passive
CEOs or entire top management teams to insuf-
ciently monitor their organizations (Bertrand and
Mullainathan, 2003; Harris and Helfat, 1997; Hart,
1983), allowing self-interested managers inside the
organization to misrepresent, distort, and withhold
information for their own interests (Bidwell, 2012;
Eccles and White, 1988; Nickerson and Zenger,
2004; Osterloh and Frey, 2000; Pierce, 2012;
Shleifer and Vishny, 1997; Williamson, 1985).
As Williamson (1985) repeatedly argues, when
high-powered managerial incentives exist with
the rm, as is common in the banking industry,
the imperfect monitoring and intervention of top
managers and owners is frequently insufcient to
restrain this distortionary behavior.
We study how corporate governance changes the
role of vertical integration by examining the quality
of loans issued between 2000 and 2007 by mortgage
lenders that vary in both integration levels and gov-
ernance characteristics. We construct a rm-year
measure of lending quality as the incremental like-
lihood that a mortgage defaults if it is originated
by that lender, controlling for the loan characteris-
tics observable by external market participants. If a
lender chooses to supply its securitization unit by
unobservably lowering loan quality, this distortion
is captured by this metric.
We rst show that, on average, vertically inte-
grated lenders issue higher quality loans than
nonintegrated rms, replicating earlier research
(Demiroglu and James, 2012). We then show that
this average effect masks signicant differences
between integrated rms with strong and weak
governance. Although integrated rms with strong
governance have the lowest mortgage default like-
lihood, this relationship between integration and
default likelihood strongly increases as governance
weakens. In rms with the weakest governance,
greater integration is actually associated with
worse quality lending, the opposite of their
strong-governance counterparts. We also examine
specic governance dimensions and nd evidence
that both shareholder and board characteristics
moderate the relationship between integration and
performance, with inconsistent results on exec-
utive compensation. Our results suggest that the
advantages of vertical integration are offset in rms
with a weak governance structure, which is likely
a function of both external and internal monitoring.
Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,38: 300–321 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/smj

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT