Price-fixing Overcharges: Legal and Economic Evidence

Published date06 April 2007
Date06 April 2007
Pages59-153
DOIhttps://doi.org/10.1016/S0193-5895(06)22004-9
AuthorJohn M. Connor
PRICE-FIXING OVERCHARGES:
LEGAL AND ECONOMIC
EVIDENCE
John M. Connor
ABSTRACT
This paper surveys published economic studies and judicial decisions
that contain 1,040 quantitative estimates of overcharges of hard-core
cartels. The primary finding is that the median long-run overcharge for all
types of cartels over all time periods is 25.0%:18.8% for domestic cartels
and 31.0% for international cartels. Cartel overcharges are positively
skewed, pushing the mean overcharge for all successful cartels to 43.4%.
Convicted cartels are on average as equally effective at raising prices as
unpunished cartels, but bid-rigging conduct does display somewhat lower
mark-ups than price-fixing cartels. These findings suggest that optimal
deterrence requires that monetary penalties ought to be increased.
INTRODUCTION
Since at least 1888, hundreds of economists, historians, commissioners, and
jurists have labored mightily to assess the ‘‘effectiveness’’ of cartels. Various
criteria have been applied to evaluate cartel performance, including
Research in Law and Economics, Volume 22, 59–153
Copyright r2007 by Elsevier Ltd.
All rights of reproduction in any form reserved
ISSN: 0193-5895/doi:10.1016/S0193-5895(06)22004-9
59
longevity, stability, efficiency, and social welfare effects, but by far the
greatest attention has been lavished on market price effects.
1
The increase in
transaction prices by a sellers’ cartel is commonly called an overcharge by
economists or damages by legal writers. The overcharge rate is calculated by
comparing actual cartel-enhanced prices to some competitive benchmark
price
2
(Connor, 2004a).
A price-fixing overcharge is a transfer of income or wealth from buyers
to the members of the cartel that occurs as a result of a collusive agreement.
3
Ceteris paribus, when a cartel achieves high levels of effectiveness (i.e.,
longevity, stability, and high overcharges), it tends to generate large cus-
tomer losses in the form of loss of consumer surplus.
4
Although there
are other negative effects of price fixing, legal scholarship tends to equate
antitrust injury with the overcharge. Effective cartels are also viewed as
destructive to the competitive process in the sense that they weaken the
natural effects of demand and supply in price formation and cause dead-
weight social losses.
5
The deadweight losses result from the costs incurred by
customers when they are forced to substitute inferior substitutes, if any, the
costs incurred by the members of the cartel in managing the collusive en-
terprise, and rent-seeking behavior by the cartel such as efforts directed at
forestalling entry. In this paper, I focus on cartel overcharges as the prin-
cipal type of harm or damages created by price fixing.
The last dedicated survey of the cartel literature did not cover overcharges
(Bullock, 1901, 1905). Today textbooks of economics conventionally devote
considerable space to the market price effects of cartels (see, for example,
Carlton & Perloff, 2004, pp. 128–131, 140–145, 148–150). While empirical
studies of cartels routinely survey selected works as a prelude to the study
being presented, to my knowledge no one has published a work aimed
principally at comprehensively surveying and analyzing cartel overcharges.
This paper is aimed principally at filling this gap in the legal-economic
literature.
The size of cartel overcharges is an issue at the empirical heart of a
number of legal and economic controversies. First, knowing the size and
distribution of cartel overcharges is necessary to justify the underpinnings
of U.S. and foreign sanctions for illegal cartel conduct. Many commentators
on government fining practices have noted the absence of appropriate em-
pirical data for the rational design of such policies. Second, there is evidence
in the economic literature widely varying opinions among experts on the
critical legal-economic issue of the size of sanctions needed for optimal
deterrence of cartel formation.
JOHN M. CONNOR60
Overcharges and Cartel Fines
The Sentencing Reform Act of 1984 created the U.S. Sentencing Commission
(USSC), a judicial-branch unit charged by Congress with devising guidelines
for sentencing for the federal judiciary (USSG Advisory Group, 2003). The
first set of guidelines was promulgated in 1987, and after three years of study
and public comment was made law in 1989.The guidelines included sanctions
for organizations guilty of horizontal price fixing and bid rigging (Cohen &
Scheffman, 1989, p. 332). Although the Sherman Act of 1890 is a criminal
statute that encompasses other types of restrictive business practices, by long
tradition only horizontal price fixing and market-sharing agreements have
triggered criminal indictments by the Department of Justice (DOJ).
6
The issue of how high cartels typically raise prices was crucial when the
USSC established the fine levels for cartels. The USSC’s cartel fine levels
followed from its famous conclusion: ‘‘It is estimated that the average gain
from price fixing is 10 percent of the selling price.’’
7
The Commission added:
‘‘The purpose for specifying a percent of the volume of commerce is to avoid
the time and expense that would be required for the court to determine
actual gain or loss.’’
8
As the Sixth Circuit noted, the Sentencing Commission
‘‘opted for greater administrative convenience’’ instead of ‘‘undertaking a
specific inquiry into the actual loss in each case.’’
9
The USSC appears to have adopted the 10% presumption because its
use was advocated by the (then) head of the Antitrust Division, Douglas
Ginsburg.
10
The origin of Ginsburg’s 10% figure is not publicly known.
11
However, a prominent analysis of the issue by Cohen and Scheffman (1989)
published shortly after the Antitrust Sentencing Guidelines were promul-
gated, states that the economic evaluation of only three price-fixing con-
spiracies was particularly important in shaping Ginsburg’s views. If this
analysis is correct, a critical assumption in setting cartel fines in the United
States is supported by a surprisingly small amount of evidence.
The USSC’s 10% presumption was attacked as unreliable and overstated
almost as soon as it was issued. For example, Cohen and Scheffman (1989)
concluded that ‘‘ythere is little credible statistical evidence that would
justify the Commission’s assumptions which underlie the Antitrust Guide-
lines’’ (p. 333). ‘‘At least in price fixing cases involving a substantial volume
of commerce, ten percent is almost certainly too high’’ (p. 343). Moreover,
the specific data that the Commission uses was characterized as exaggerated:
‘‘later research has cast considerable doubt on ythese estimates, conclud-
ing that the markups, if they existed, were quite small’’ (p. 345).
Price-Fixing Overcharges 61

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT