Positive Assortative Matching: Evidence from Sports Data

AuthorAntonio Filippin,Jan C. Ours
Date01 July 2015
Published date01 July 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/irel.12096
Positive Assortative Matching: Evidence from
Sports Data
*
ANTONIO FILIPPIN and JAN C. VAN OURS
It is difcult to establish empirically whether or not there is positive assortative
matching in the labor market. We use longitudinal data from a 24-hour relay mara-
thon in Belluno, Italy, in which participants are afliated with teams, to study group
dynamics in a manner that closely resembles workersaccessions to and separations
from rms. In our dataset the productivity of the individual agents is measured and
we exploit this by investigating the determinants of accessions, separations, and
assortative matching. We nd support for the existence of positive assortative
matching; i.e., better runners moving to better teams in subsequent years.
Introduction
Firms can use hiring and separations as tools to increase productivity and
prots. Firms may hire young, inexperienced workers who have just entered
the labor market or more experienced workers who have quit or been let go
from another job. Separations may occur through layoffs, quits, or retirement.
That there is positive assortative matching, i.e., better workers tend to move to
better rms, looks like a natural consequence. However, this fact is not well
established in the literature. The way rms and workers form a match is the
topic of both theoretical and empirical research. If there are complementarities
in the production function, it is optimal when the best rms match with the
best workers. Then, a random allocation of workers across rms would imply
a loss of output. Similarly, if characteristics of rms and workers are substi-
tutes in production a random allocation is not optimal either.
It is not easy to establish whether or not there is assortative matching and if so
whether it is positive or negative. Originally, studies used wage data to investigate
*The authorsafliations are, respectively, Department of Economics, University of Milan, Italy, and IZA
(Bonn). Email: antonio.lippin@unimi.it; Department of Economics, CentER, Tilburg University, the Neth-
erlands; Department of Economics, University of Melbourne, Parkville, Australia; CEPR (London); CESifo
(Munich); IZA (Bonn); Email: vanours@uvt.nl.
JEL: J14, J24, J31.
The authors thank the organizers of the San Martino Marathon for making the data available, and Lorenzo
Cappellari and Giovanni Pica as well as participants to the XXXVI SAEe conference (Malaga) for helpful
suggestions. The usual disclaimers apply.
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS, Vol. 54, No. 3 (July 2015). ©2015 Regents of the University of California
Published by Wiley Periodicals, Inc., 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA, and 9600 Garsington
Road, Oxford, OX4 2DQ, UK.
401
the matching between workers and rms. Worker xed effects and rm xed
effects are derived from wage equations estimated on matched workerrm data.
The correlation between the two types of xed effects is interpreted as being infor-
mative about the existence and the nature of assortative matching. Abowd,
Kramarz, and Margolis (1999) initially used this idea to analyze French worker
firm data and found that the correlation between the two types of xed effects is
small or negative. Abowd et al. (2009), applying a similar method to U.S.earnings
data, found that the correlation between worker and rm effects is close to zero.
Andrews et al. (2008) argued that estimation errors can cause a downward
bias in the estimated correlation between worker and rm xed effects. An over-
estimate of a worker effect on average leads to an underestimate of a rm xed
effect. This bias is bigger the fewer workers move between rms. Using German
matched workerrm data they found that this bias can be considerable but not
sufciently large to remove the negative correlation between worker and rm
xed effects. Andrews et al. (2012), also using German data, addressed the
limited mobility biasby focusing on rms for which the number of movers is
large and found that there is signicant positive assortative matching.
Eeckhout and Kircher (2011) and Lopes de Melo (2013) argued that the
method of Abowd, Kramarz, and Margolis (1999) did not properly measure sort-
ing because wages are not monotone in the rm type. Wages of a given worker
have an inverted U-shape around the optimal allocation. Wages can be lower
not only when the worker matches with a bad rm, but also, more surprisingly,
with a very good rm. The reason is that in the case of complementarities higher
productivity rms pay a very high cost if they match with a bad worker, because
it destroys their opportunity to match with a better one. Hence, they need to be
compensated for a suboptimal match via a lower wage. This implies that the
compensation is the highest when a worker meets the right rm and that the
wage schedule is not monotonically increasing in the rm type. Consequently,
standard rm xed effects are not correlated with the true type of the rm.
Lopes de Melo (2013) suggested that the correlation between the xed
effects of workers and the average xed effects of his/her coworkers should be
used as an indicator for assortative matching. Applying this idea to Brazilian
matched workerrm data Lopes de Melo (2008) found evidence of sorting.
However, this procedure and the use of wage data in general can only be
informative about the intensity of assortative matching, but not about its sign.
More recently, Bartolucci and Devicienti (2013) exploited the movers in a
matched workerrm dataset, showing that there is positive assortative match-
ing. They used rmsprot and workerswage to build a ranking of their
respective types. Relying upon such proxies they found that the direction of
assortative matching is positive, while the opposite would emerge estimating
the xed effects of a wage equation.
402 / ANTONIO FILIPPIN AND JAN C. VAN OURS

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT