Pay dispersion among the top management team and outside directors: Its impact on firm risk and firm performance

Date01 January 2018
Published date01 January 2018
AuthorHaemin Dennis Park,Mingxiang Li,María del Carmen Triana,Pankaj C. Patel
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/hrm.21872
HR SCIENCE FORUM
Pay dispersion among the top management team and outside
directors: Its impact on firm risk and firm performance
Pankaj C. Patel
1
| Mingxiang Li
2
| María del Carmen Triana
3
| Haemin Dennis Park
4
1
Villanova University, Villanova, Pennsylvania
2
Florida Atlantic University, Boca Raton,
Florida
3
University of WisconsinMadison, Madison,
Wisconsin
4
University of Texas at Dallas, Richardson,
Texas
Correspondence
Pankaj C. Patel, Villanova University, Villanova
School of Business, 800 Lancaster Ave.,
Villanova, PA 19401.
E-mail: pankaj.patel@villanova.edu
Two key groups central to improving firm performance are the top management team (TMT)
and the board of directors. Executives undertake strategic actions, whereas board members ful-
fill their resource provision and monitoring roles. Drawing on tournament theory and equity
theory, we propose that high pay dispersion among outside directors and the TMT is positively
associated with strategic risk, whereas high (low) TMT pay dispersion and low (high) outside
director pay dispersion are positively associated with firm performance. Our predictor is the
unexplained component of horizontal pay dispersion, or the residual of pay dispersion resulting
from regressing pay on observable firm, industry, period, and individual characteristics. Our
results highlight the importance of unexplained pay dispersion for TMTs, but not for boards of
directors, in improving firm performance.
KEYWORDS
dual-agency framework, pay dispersion, performance, relative deprivation, strategic risk,
tournament theory
1|INTRODUCTION
An important question facing companies today is how to incentivize
organizational leaders to improve firm performance. Two key groups
leading organizations are the top management team (TMT) and the
board of directors. Prior work on executive compensation has drawn
on tournament theory to explain the relevance of pay dispersion
among top-level executives in driving firm performance (Connelly,
Haynes, Tihanyi, Gamache, & Devers, 2013). Disproportionate differ-
ences in pay induce executive tournaments. Referred to elsewhere as
CEO pay slice (Bebchuk, Cremers, & Peyer, 2011), CEO and average
executive pay gap (Henderson & Fredrickson, 2001), or pay variation
among TMT executives (Ji & Oh, 2014), pay dispersion in the upper
echelons is the mainstay in the executive compensation literature
(Gabaix & Landier, 2008).
By contrast, the horizontal variation in pay among board mem-
bers is less explored and could interact with TMT pay dispersion to
influence strategic risk or firm performance. Although board members
fulfill both resource provision and monitoring roles, it is unclear
whether individual board member pay is sufficient or whether hori-
zontal pay dispersion among board members could further improve
firm performance. Board members are less likely to compete with
one another in a tournament setting, and therefore, the tenets of
tournament theory may not apply for board members. However, two
complementary theories to tournament theory that could explain the
value of pay disparity among board members are equity theory and
relative deprivation theory (Crosby, 1976, 1984), which have been
widely used to study pay dispersion (Downes & Choi, 2014). Equity
theory (Adams, 1963, 1965) contends that individuals evaluate the
ratio of their outputs relative to inputs compared to that of similar
persons referred to as referent others. If the individual making the
comparison perceives their ratio to be lower than that of their refer-
ent others, they initiate efforts to equalize the inequity by changing
their level of inputs (e.g., working harder) and/or changing their level
of outputs (e.g., asking for a raise). Similar to equity theory, relative
deprivation theory calls for parity.
Although past work has found mixed support for the association
between TMT pay dispersion and firm performance (Henderson &
Fredrickson, 2001), incentivizing outside board members who may
strive to lower inequity relative to other similar board members could
influence the association between TMT pay dispersion and firm per-
formance. Social comparison induced by outside director (i.e., board
members who are not firm executives) pay dispersion could be a the-
oretical undergird to developing a deeper understanding of the
DOI: 10.1002/hrm.21872
Hum Resour Manage. 2018;57:177192. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/hrm © 2017 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. 177
association between TMT pay dispersion and firm performance. As
such, we pose two research questions based on tournament theory,
equity theory, and relative deprivation theory.
First, we posit that having higher pay dispersion for both the
TMT and outside board members could exacerbate strategic risk.
Greater pay dispersion among TMT members induces greater risk
taking (Boyd, Franco Santos, & Shen, 2012; Kini & Williams, 2011). If
pay dispersion is greater among board members, board members
could strive to increase their value by focusing more on resource pro-
vision roles. It could generally be presumed that board members
would weigh their time and effort between their monitoring role by
watching executives' actions and their resource provision role by
offering resources and advice to executives (Hillman & Dalziel, 2003).
Although we do not posit that pay dispersion reduces the board
members' focus on monitoring, we propose that incentive differences
may prime the board members' resource provision role because those
who have earned the greatest amount from incentives over time will
be motivated to use their networks to provide resources for firms
that have increased their wealth. Likewise, those who have not
earned as much in total compensation may hope to help the firm so
that they may have better prospects for wealth in the future. Disper-
sion in pay among the board of directors could, therefore, prime
board members across the pay dispersion scale to more actively
search for information and resources to improve their odds of reduc-
ing pay gaps. Such priming also puts additional pressure on high rank-
ing board members (in both pay and status) to up the antein their
resource provision roles. Pay dispersion among board members thus
primes competitive behaviorcontinued cooperation in monitoring,
but also provides necessary competition to fulfill resource provision
roles.
Second, we propose that high (low) TMT pay dispersion and low
(high) outside director pay dispersion will be positively associated
with firm performance. When pay dispersion is high in the TMT,
executives may undertake more strategic actions to improve their
chances of advancing in pay, leading to increased firm risk (Conyon,
Peck, & Sadler, 2001; Kini & Williams, 2011). Although outside direc-
tors do not compete with executives for pay, low pay dispersion
among outside directors should limit the sense of relative deprivation
or inequity within the board, reduce conflict among directors, and
improve cohesion and communication. This in turn can improve the
monitoring and control function of the board when TMT pay disper-
sion is high. In contrast, when TMT pay dispersion is low, greater pay
dispersion among directors could shift the focus of outside directors
from monitoring and controlling to improving their relative pay
through the resource provision and promotion of strategic actions
(cf. Festinger, 1954) that can improve firm performance.
In testing the above research questions, we operationalize unex-
plainedpay dispersion. As recommended by Downes and Choi
(2014) a statistical process that objectively evaluates explainedpay
dispersion and creates a residual term that is useful for measuring
unexplainedpay dispersion is excellent for dealing with panel or
archival data(page 63). To measure unexplained dispersion Mahy,
Rycx, and Volral (2011) computed a residual from an individual-
worker regression using individual-level characteristics as predictors
and included the residual to predict plant-level productivity. The
intuition for using residual is as follows. Publicly traded firms used in
the current sample must meet performance expectations. The princi-
pals can observe outcomes (performance) and given low effort-
outcome correlation contexts, such as the upper echelons, individual
performance cannot be clearly attributed. As such, factors such as
executive (e.g., education, tenure), firm, industry, and period-related
drivers of compensation can be explained by institutional, political,
and social factors. A residual derived after controlling for observable
firm, industry, period, and executive/board characteristics captures
unobserved effort, talent, and abilities that drive performance from
one year to another. Although the residual also includes noise and
luck, the share of these factors would be lower in the upper echelons
due to institutional and social pressures on pay limits and incentives
to reduce perceptions of noise or luck explaining pay dispersion
among high-profile individuals competing in corporate labor markets.
The proposed framework makes two contributions. First, drawing
on equity theory (Adams, 1963, 1965) and relative deprivation theory
(Crosby, 1976, 1984), we provide novel insights on board pay disper-
sion. Although retainers are a major component of board member
compensation, recent work shows that awarding stock options to
directors increases firm risk (Lim & McCann, 2013a, 2013b). For
instance, a study by Yermack (2004) finds that for a $1,000 change in
shareholder wealth, compensation of outside directors goes up by
11 cents after controlling for board and board member characteris-
tics. Moving from the influence of individual to group-level board
member compensation dynamics, we propose and test the influence
of pay dispersion at the board level by examining how pay (total
rewards) dispersion among the board and TMT jointly affect firm
strategic risk-taking behavior and firm performance.
Second, based on the dual-agency framework, high TMT and low
board pay dispersion interact to improve firm performance. In con-
trast to prior work focusing on TMT pay dispersion, this study
assesses the influence of pay dispersion among outside directors on
firm performance and risk. Because both groups have been shown to
influence firm performance, it is important to understand the joint
relationship between TMT pay and director pay on firm risk-taking
and performance. Considering incentives of both groups of agents
(board and TMT) through the dual-agency lens may help us under-
stand when firms improve performance and how to manage incen-
tives among the elites who run organizations.
2|THEORY DEVELOPMENT AND
HYPOTHESES
Compensation is central to eliciting effort and risk bearing
(Eisenhardt, 1989; Jensen & Murphy, 1990). Agency theory focuses
on incentivizing individual agents, whereas tournament theory and
relative deprivation/equity theory explain the influence of relative
incentives on performance (Connelly et al., 2013; Henderson & Fre-
drickson, 2001). Pay dispersion, or the differences in relative pay, are
classified into vertical and horizontal pay dispersion (Shaw, 2014).
Vertical pay dispersion refers to differences in relative pay between
the highest paid executive and an average employee. Vertical pay dis-
persion is elemental to inducing promotion tournaments among low-
178 PATEL ET AL.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT