Merger Simulation

Pages269-309
269
CHAPTER XI
MERGER SIMULATION
A. Introduction to Merger Simulation
Merger simulation can generate a quantitative prediction of the likely
unilateral price effects of a proposed merger.1 Merger simulation has
been used extensively at the antititrust agencies, including in the
EchoStar transaction discussed in Chapter VI, and in the proposed
WorldCom/Sprint merger discussed in Appendix 1. In addition, merger
simulation played a prominant role in the district court decision declining
to enjoin the Oracle/PeopleSoft merger.2
The basic idea is to combine what can be observed easily, such as
prices and shares, with reasonable assumptions about the behavior of
market participants in a manner that allows the calculation of the implied
unilateral effects. Merger simulation can illuminate important factors in
determining the unilateral effects of a merger, as well as how and to what
degree they matter. This chapter discusses the strengths and weaknesses
of merger simulation generally and of specific models used in merger
simulation.
1. As explained below, combining the merging firms, and hence
internalizing the competition among their merging products, may alter
profit incentives and cause the merged firm to raise prices or reduce
output without any sort of coordination with competitors.
2. United States v. Oracle Corp., 331 F. Supp. 2d 1098, 1122 (N.D. Cal.
2004) (“Despite the problems with qualitative analyses, modern
econometric methods hold promise in analyzing differentiated products
unilateral effects cases. Merger simulation models may allow more
precise estimations of likely competitive effects and eliminate the need to,
or lessen the impact of, the arbitrariness inherent in defining the relevant
market.”). But see id. at 1172-73 (finding that government’s case was
“devoid of any thorough econometric analysis” such as calculation of
diversion ratios or cross-elasticities of demand).
Econometrics in Antitrust
270
Merger simulation has been used mainly with differentiated
consumer products, and this chapter examines three models of consumer
demand that have been used in that context. The first four sections of
this chapter provide non-technical introductions to (1) the concept of
merger simulation and its proper use, (2) unilateral merger effects with
differentiated consumer products and the role of demand elasticities, (3)
three models of consumer demand that have been used in merger
simulation with differentiated consumer products, and (4) the advantages
and disadvantages of these three models in merger simulation.
Because economic modeling never fully captures real-world
competitive processes, the ultimate test for the reliability of merger
simulation is how well it predicts the effects of actual mergers. To date,
little is known about that, nor about the accuracy of any other method for
predicting the competitive effects of mergers. For now, the reliability of
merger simulation is judged on the basis of the “fit” between the model
and the industry.
Merger simulation with differentiated consumer products employs
the Bertrand oligopoly model. The Bertrand model assumes competitors
interact just once, each maximizing its short-run profit, with price as the
sole dimension of competition. Bertrand equilibrium is reached when all
competitors are happy with their prices, given rivals’ prices.3 The
Bertrand model is best employed where its assumptions comport
reasonably well with the factual setting of the industry in which the
merging parties compete.4
Assessing the fit between the Bertrand model and real world
economic conditions is largely a matter of evaluating how well it
explains the past. One important aspect of fit is the degree to which the
predicted price-cost margins, which characterize the intensity of
competition, correspond to observed margins. Also important is how
well the model would have predicted responses to significant cost
changes or new product introductions occurring in the recent past.
Finally, it is important to evaluate the role of nonprice competition, e.g.,
3. For a discussion of the Bertrand model, see DENNIS W. CARLTON &
JEFFREY M. PERLOFF, MODERN INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION 166-72 (3d
ed. 2000).
4. For further discussion of when the Bertrand model fits the industry well
enough to offer useful predictions, see Gregory J. Werden, Luke M.
Froeb & David T. Scheffman, A Daubert Discipline for Merger
Simulation, ANTITRUST, Summer 2004, at 89.
Merger Simulation
271
advertising and product positioning, as well as the strategic behavior in
repeated competitor interaction, all of which are outside the model.
Merger simulation holds such things as product characteristics and
advertising constant, which can result in misleading predictions,
particularly if aspects of marketing strategy interact in important ways
with pricing. Merger simulation also examines only the unilateral
incentive that may exist for the merged firm to raise price.5 If some form
of pricing coordination (e.g., overt collusion) is likely to exist before the
merger, or arise as a result of the merger, merger simulation may not
offer any useful insights to the merger’s competitive effects.
If the Bertrand model reasonably approximates competitor behavior
before and after a merger, simulation may be helpful in gaining insight
into likely postmerger price changes. Merger simulation can provide
reasonable, if rough, estimates of a differentiated products merger’s price
effects. But significant weight should be placed on the predictions of a
merger simulation only if the modeling assumptions and the simulation
predictions are consistent with the picture of the competitive landscape
painted by the totality of the evidence. Merger simulation can usefully
complement a traditional, fact-intensive analysis of consumers,
competitors, and the institutional setting of an industry, but cannot
substitute for it.
B. Unilateral Effects Analysis and the Role of Demand Elasticities
The basic idea of unilateral effects from differentiated products
mergers is straightforward: Prior to a proposed merger, the producers of
Brands A and B presumably are happy with their prices, given the prices
of rival brands. Thus, a small price increase would reduce profits
because the revenues lost from the resulting sales reduction would
exceed the cost reduction associated with producing less. If Brands A
and B compete, and the price of either is raised, some of its customers
would switch to the other product. The merger of the producers of
Brands A and B would alter the profit-maximization calculus, because
some of the sales lost from increasing the price of either brand would be
5. Unilateral effects may occur when products produced by the merging
parties are close substitutes in consumption. The merger may create a
significant incentive to raise the prices of products that had been sold
separately, if a substantial proportion of the sales lost by one merging
product due to a higher price flow to a product that the merger brings
under common ownership.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT