Appendix IV. Issues In Scanner Data

Pages431-462
431
APPENDIX IV
ISSUES IN SCANNER DATA
A. Introduction
The past decade has witnessed substantial developments in the
quantitative analysis of horizontal mergers. Several factors account for
these changes. First, the quantity and quality of data available to
estimate the degree of substitutability among competing products has
increased dramatically. Second, this increase has been accompanied by a
substantial decrease in the price of computing power required to analyze
the data. Third, there has been an increased focus on the possibility of
competitive harm from unilateral market conduct, particularly in mergers
involving differentiated products. However, understanding how
consumers substitute among competing products also contributes to the
analysis of possible competitive harm from coordinated market behavior.
How consumers substitute across products as relative prices change
is relevant to understanding the potential price effects of mergers.1 This
information, contained in the own- and cross-price elasticities of demand
at retail,2 is most frequently used as a means for predicting the unilateral
incentives to increase prices postmerger. In the context of differentiated
consumer goods, the term “unilateral effects” refers to the fact that a
1. Of course, the own- and cross-price elasticities of the demand faced by
manufacturers (wholesale demand) are more directly relevant to the
market definition and competitive effects analyses in the U.S. Department
of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission’s Horizontal Merger
Guidelines. The properties of demand of consumers (the demand at
retail) are relevant because they have implications for wholesale demand.
2. The elasticity of some variable x with respect to another variable y is the
percentage change in x that arises from a 1% increase in y. For example,
the own-price elasticity of the demand for widgets is the percentage
change in the quantity of widgets demanded given a 1% increase in their
price.
Econometrics in Antitrust
432
merger of competitors creates an incentive to increase price (all else
being equal) to the extent that there are significant substitution
possibilities between the (now) jointly-owned products. In this setting,
the existence of credible information about demand elasticities is
important. Having a good estimate of how substitutable these products
are helps the analyst predict more accurately whether these unilateral
incentives to raise price are substantial or minuscule.3
Until recently, economists had to rely on relatively simple
quantitative and qualitative information when performing merger
analyses. Resources such as surveys, analyses of shift in share, or
internal company documents did not permit quantification of the degree
of substitutability among the merging firms’ products. While these
3. It has become conventional to analyze these unilateral pricing incentives
using static oligopoly models in which firms compete on the basis of
price. The static oligopoly game that models firms’ pricing decisions is
sometimes referred to as the “Bertrand” pricing game, named after Joseph
Bertrand, Review of “Theorie Mathematique de la Richess Sociale” and
Recherche sur les Principes Mathematiques de las Theorie des Richesses,
499-508 JOURNAL DE SAVANTS (1883), who was the first economist to
study it. This is the framework used most often to examine unilateral
effects in merger analysis. Whether these static models provide an
appropriate benchmark for predicting the consequences of a horizontal
merger is somewhat controversial. See, e.g., Franklin M. Fisher, It Takes
t* to Tango: Trading Coalitions with Fixed Prices, 56 REV. ECON. STUD.
391 (1989); Carl Shapiro, Market Power and Mergers in Durable-Good
Industries: Comments, 32 J.L. & ECON. S227 (1989). Without attempting
to resolve that controversy here, note that several recent studies have
attempted to test the validity of static oligopoly models. See, e.g., Aviv
Nevo, Measuring Market Power in the Ready-to-Eat Cereal Industry, 69
ECONOMETRICA 307 (2001); Joris Pinske & Margaret Slade, Mergers,
Brand Competition, and the Price of a Pint (2001) (mimograph, on file at
the Department of Economics, University of British Columbia); Jerry
Hausman & Gregory Leonard, The Competitive Effects of a New Product
Introduction: A Case Study (2000) (mimeograph, on file at the
Massachusetts Institute of Technology); David Genesove & Wallace
Mullin, Testing Static Oligopoly Models: Conduct and Cost in the Sugar
Industry, 1890-1914, 29 RAND J. ECON. 355 (1998); Catherine Wolfram,
Measuring Duopoly Power in the British Electricity Market, 89 AM.
ECON. REV. 805 (1999). Most of these studies suggest that the static
oligopoly models yield reasonably accurate predictions of pricing
behavior.
Issues in Scanner Data
433
sources of information are useful and continue to play an important role
in merger analysis, a well-executed econometric analysis of demand may
enable an economist to infer not only that a set of goods are substitutes,
but also what volume of sales will switch from product X to product Y
given a specific price increase for product X.
The value of information on demand elasticities is not limited to
studies of unilateral pricing incentives. Information about the degree of
substitutability among potentially competing products also is important
in determining the incentive and ability to engage in coordinated post-
merger pricing.
It is interesting to note that marketing professionals also use
elasticity information taken from econometric analyses of scanner data.
Manufacturers of consumer products estimate systems of demand
equations to help determine optimal prices for their products. Scanner
data drawn from consumers’ actual purchases provide a wealth of
information that can be used to describe and analyze consumer demand.
While the quantitative estimation of demand relationships can make
substantial contributions to merger analysis, practitioners nevertheless
must confront and resolve difficult econometric and conceptual issues.
This appendix attempts to identify a number of those issues that
researchers and practitioners may consider to make the quantitative
estimation of demand relationships using scanner data more applicable to
merger review. Specifically:
1. What is the best way to aggregate data across observational units
and across time?
2. Is it necessary to address the possible endogeneity of explanatory
variables?
3. Is it possible to construct meaningful measures of the accuracy
of predicted price changes?
4. Can one easily translate elasticities estimated with retail-level
data into wholesale-level elasticities?
These are difficult questions, and this appendix does not attempt to
provide definitive answers to them. Its purpose is to provoke further
discussion and research into these issues, with the ultimate goal of
improving the quality of antitrust analysis.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT