FLSA Working Hours Reform: Worker Well‐Being Effects in an Economic Framework

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/irel.12112
Published date01 October 2015
Date01 October 2015
FLSA Working Hours Reform: Worker
Well-Being Effects in an Economic Framework*
LONNIE GOLDEN
This article discusses a model developed to predict the effects of recently pro-
posed amendments to the FLSA workweek and overtime provisions. The model
contrasts allowing compensatory time for overtime pay for private nonexempt
employees to rights to requestreduced hours. Hours demanded are likely to rise
for workers who request comp time, undermining the intention of family-friendli-
ness and alleviating overemployment, unless accompanied by offsetting policies
that would prevent the denied use or forced use of comp time and that resurrect
some monetary deterrent effect. A unique survey shows that the preference for
time over money and comp time is relatively more prevalent among exempt, long
hours and women workers; thus, worker welfare is likely better served if comp
time were incorporated into an individualized, employee-initiated right to request.
Introduction and Overview: The Current and Future FLSA
Several reform proposals are currently before the United States Congress
that would amend the Fair Labor Standards Act (FLSA). The standard work-
week and overtime provisions of this law that dene working lives in the
United States have not been amended since 1985. There are fundamental polit-
ical differences over how to amend the FLSA. On the one side, the House
Representatives passed H.R. 1406 in May of 2013; its companion proposal,
the Family Friendly and Workplace Flexibility Act(S. 1626), has been intro-
duced in the Senate. These bills would amend the FLSA to allow private-
sector employers to substitute compensatory (comp) time for overtime pay, if
an employee signs on to such an agreement. Employers would compensate
employees with future time off at the rate of 1.5 hours for every hour of over-
*The authorsafliation is Penn State UniversityAbington College, Abington, Pennsylvania. Email:
Lmg5@psu.edu.
The author would like to thank the anonymous referees, the editor, Peter Berg, Tesfayi Gebreselassie,
and Ross Eisenbrey. All views expressed are the authors.
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS, Vol. 54, No. 4 (October 2015). ©2015 Regents of the University of California
Published by Wiley Periodicals, Inc., 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA, and 9600 Garsington
Road, Oxford, OX4 2DQ, UK.
717
time worked; public-sector employers were granted this option in the 1985
amendment
1
. Virtually identical legislation introduced in the Senate (S.1623)
would institute a exible credit-hour programthat would allow an employee to
work excess hours beyond their typical, nonovertime number of required hours, in
order to build up hours of paid time off to be taken at a later date, at straight time
value. However, a workers use of accrued comp time credits can be denied if the
use would unduly disruptthe operations of the business or if the worker has not
notied their employer within what the latter regards as a reasonable amount of
notice prior.
The other side of the debate on the proposed amendments regards these propos-
als as largely a wolf in sheeps clothing,designed to benet employers with little
if any benet to employees, if not harm.
2
This side has proposed alternative FLSA
reforms, such as The Healthy Families Act(H.R. 1286/S. 631), a national paid
sick days minimum standard, to earn up to seven job-protected paid sick days
annually, and The Paid Vacation Act(H. R. 2096), which would require that
employers provide a minimum of one week of paid annual leave to eligible
employees. More pertinently, this side has introduced The Flexibility for Work-
ing Families Act(H.R. 2559, S. 1248), which would institute an individual
employee the right to requesta change in four terms of employment: the number
of work hours, daily scheduling times or being on call, location where the
employee is required to work, and length of notication the employee receives of
work schedule assignments.
3
The burden would be placed on an employer to:
1
In 2015, there is a proposed update of the U.S. Department of Labor regulations last visited in 2004,
that set minimum salary levels for a job to be considered exempt and also a maximum salary level to be
considered covered. Other FLSA regulatory reforms covered the issues of compliance and potential viola-
tions, such as mis-classication, as exempt(e.g., Levine and Lewin 2006; Belman and Belzer 1997), off-
the-clock work (Faraz, Shamsi, and Bashir 2013) and guaranteeing minimum weekly hours for hourly work-
ers, particularly in retail trade (Lambert, Haley-Lock, and Henly 2012).
2
Amendments in earlier comp-time proposals for private-sector employees provided double damages to
workers if they were coerced into selecting comp time over pay, and excluded workers with fewer than
1000 hours per year; however, they had allowed far more accumulation of credits per annum than the cur-
rent bills80 or 160 hours. In the decades prior to the comp-time proposals, there were reform proposals to
raise the overtime pay premium up to at least double time (see Whittaker 2005; Hamermesh 2006). The
2011 Payroll Fraud Prevention Act(S.770) would eliminate current protections allowing employers to
exclude independent contractors in their workforces from overtime pay requirements.
3
The legislation is modeled after the statutory right to request exible work arrangements adopted in
Anglo countries abroad, including the UK, New Zealand, Australia, and Northern Ireland. The most com-
mon request is for a reduced workweek and the vast majority of employee requests are indeed granted by
employers (Boushey 2011). Vermont is the rst state to allow employees to request arrangements to
telecommute, job share, work part time, or adjust their schedules. San Francisco is the rst city to have a
right-to-requestordinance: employers with twenty or more staff provide employees in caregiver roles a
right to request a predictable or exible work schedule. On July 14, 2015, the "Schedules that Work" Act
was re-introduced into both houses of Congress, expanding the scope of work scheduling modications that
could be requested (see footnote #37).
718 / LONNIE GOLDEN
respond to a written request within a reasonable period; deny the request only
with sufcient reason; and propose an alternative change to the employees hours,
times, place, or notication. In addition, an employeesright to refuseadded
hours, such as mandatory overtime, was proposed in previous bills, but the scope
covered only selected health-care occupations.
This paper addresses whether a blend of all these proposals might serve well
as comprehensive FLSA reform. Can we preserve the original intent of the
FLSAinclusive labor law to protect workers with little bargaining leverage
from starvation wages and intolerable hours,
4
while also modifying it to take
account of the increasing heterogeneity of work-hours preferences in the work-
force? The FLSA overtime rules were enacted to address a chronic market fail-
urea labor market that often proved unable to transform extended
workweeks into work opportunities for the unemployed or underemployed. It
was designed to allow employers the latitude to use unlimited overtime hours,
as long as they were willing to pay the premium.
5
It applied a monetary incen-
tive rather than statutory deterrent, ostensibly to make the employer bear much
of the potential marginal social spillover costsreduced employment, health,
and nonwork (leisure) time.
6
While most advocates of reform agree it is desirable to make work hours
more exible,the question of focus here will be on which set of FLSA
amendments would be most benecial for the more than 80 million nonexempt
workers in the United States, and also perhaps, for some exemptworkers.
Which bills would live up to their own titles suggesting concern for well-being
and exibility for employees?
7
Such an analysis may dispassionately frame
and therefore help to depolarize the political discussion.
4
Bernstein and Eisenbrey (2014) argue that the initial law protected leisure, family, and social time,
without actually forbidding employers from scheduling overtime work, and that the salary testmust be
updated to continue this also see Linder (2002).
5
See Ehrenberg (1986) and Rottenberg (1995) for contrasting views of the role of hours regulation.
6
See Bernstein and Eisenbrey (2014).
7
Estimates of the number of workers covered by the FLSA that are also nonexemptfrom the hours
tracking and overtime pay provisions are, by nature, scarce and imprecise, given the gray areas and discrep-
ancies in implementation by employers but could be as many as 80 million workers (Hamermesh 2002).
The U.S. Government Accountability Ofce (1999) estimated that between 20 and 27 percent of the full-
time workforce were bona de executive, administrative, or professional employees that qualify under the
white-collar exemption.The Wage and Hour Division of the U.S. Department of Labor estimated that
about 67 percent of those employed were nonexempt.In 2002, there were an estimated 67 million
employees that were potentially nonexempt and an estimated 31 million were potentially exempt (Mayer
2004). The GAO (1999) considered employersrequest to add a new exempt categorythe knowledge
workerif they were highly paid and highly skilled. After this, the Bush administration chose to exempt
highly compensatedemployees whose salary was above $100,000, even if they mainly performed manual
or clerical work. Various court decisions have swung back and forth regarding which specic occupations
are exemptor covered and what is considered coveredtime as work.
FLSA Hours Reforms and Economic Well-Being / 719

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT