‘Fits and fancies’: the Taylor Review, the construction of preference and labour market segmentation

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/irj.12229
AuthorBethania Antunes,Kirsty Newsome,Sian Moore,Stephanie Tailby
Date01 November 2018
Published date01 November 2018
Fits and fancies: the Taylor Review, the
construction of preference and labour
market segmentation
Sian Moore, Stephanie Tailby,
Bethania Antunes and Kirsty Newsome
ABSTRACT
The Taylor Review asserts that certain groups are also more likely to place a greater
importance on exibility such as carers, women, those with disabilities and older
workers. This article draws upon the experiences of workers on non-standard
contracts to explore the notion of worker preference and to expose how the discourse
of worklife balance is usurped to provide justication for exibility in the interest of
employers rather than workers, reconstructing labour market segregation.
1 INTRODUCTION
Good Work: The Taylor Review of Modern Working Practices opens with a statement
of the Review Panelssingle overriding ambitionthat [A]ll work in the UK econ-
omy should be fair and decent with realistic scope for development and fullment
(Taylor, 2017: 7). Bales (2018: 56) notes the borrowing of terminology from, without
effort to align with, the notion of decent workadvocated by the International La-
bour Organisation. Its Decent Work Agenda is based upon job creation, the promo-
tion of rights at work, social protection and social dialogue with gender equality as
a crosscutting objective (ILO, 2008). With the exception of job creation, these princi-
ples have little interest for the Taylor Review. This evasion is most obviously because
the Taylor Review nds virtue in the British wayof minimum statutory labour stan-
dards and associated minimal regulation of work relations and employment. Labour
market challenges are acknowledged: a relatively high rate of low pay, incidence of in-
work poverty, stagnant real wage growth and poor productivity performance. Yet
(and now invoking international comparison) emphasis is given to the success of
the UKsexiblelabour market in creating jobs, including exible jobs, which open
up work to people with different needs and priorities and at different stages of life
(Taylor, 2017: 7). Indeed, the shift towards more exible forms of working’—or
atypical employment’—in recent decades (Taylor, 2017: 23) is cast as supply-side
led. As the labour force has become more diverse, people are looking for work that
suits their individual lifestyle and preferences(Taylor, 2017: 26). They choose to
Sian Moore and Bethania Antunes, Business School, University of Greenwich, London, UK, Stephanie
Tailby, Faculty of Business and Law, University of the West of England, Bristol, UK and Kirsty Newsome,
Shefeld University Management School, Shefeld, UK. Correspondence should be addressed to Professor
Sian Moore, Business School, University of Greenwich, Park Row, London SE10 9LS, UK; email:
s.moore@greenwich.ac.uk
Industrial Relations Journal 49:5-6, 403419
ISSN 0019-8692
© 2018 Brian Towers (BRITOW) and John Wiley & Sons Ltd
make trade-offsin the rewards of work’—as between pay and hours, job security
and exibilityin pursuit of their lifestyle preferences. On the principle that society
benets from allowing individuals to participate in the labour market in a way that
suits them(Taylor, 2017: 26), the recommendation is for the law to remain permis-
sive, enabling workers to strike individual bargains with employers rather than being
constrained by prescriptive statutory standards.
This article focuses on the Taylor Reviews claim that
Certain groups are also more likely to place greater importance on exibility such as carers, women,
those with disabilities and older workers Flexibility can allow these groups to participate more fully
in the labour market by enabling them to balance work around other priorities. (Taylor, 2017: 15)
The next section, following this introduction, begins to unpack the claim, rst by ex-
amining the way preference is constructed. Taylors methodology imputes preference
of lifestyle to individuals on the basis of extant patterningby gender, age and
dis/abilityof employment at the macro level. It assumes choice without attending
to constraints. It usurps, we argue, the discourse of worklife balance (WLB) to pro-
vide justication for employer freedom to use atypicalcontracts to shift the risks and
costs of employment to workers. Following a discussion of methods, the critique of
the Taylor Reviews analysis and recommendations is supported by qualitative data
in the form of worker case studies, gathered over 2016/17 in research for the Low
Pay Commission (LPC) concerning the impact of non-standard contracts (atypical
employment in Taylor Review terms) on the National Living Wage (NLW). The nd-
ings explore the construction of preference rst through the lens of labour market in-
clusion and second through the lens of WLB, distinguishing between employer-
oriented and worker-oriented temporal exibilities.
2 LABOUR MARKET INEQUALITY AS LIFESTYLE CHOICE
Taylor encourages a view of quality work less in terms of objective measures than
through the perspective and preferences of the job seeker or job holder. This is on
the principle that individualsmotivations (or what economists would call tastes
for work) differ and their ranking of job quality dimensions will be personal or idio-
syncratic (Taylor, 2017: 12). For Taylor (2017: 28) people look for work that suits
their individual lifestyles and preferences.
Work preference is a focus of academic debate that has been characterised by con-
troversy. In addressing preference typetheories of womens disproportionate repre-
sentation in part-time employment (Hakim, 2002) and explanations in terms of
structural constraint (Ginn et al., 1996; McRae, 2003), Gash (2008) sets out the chal-
lenges of working preference measurement. These include the inability of current data
to distinguish between realand accommodatedpreferences, the last denoting
choice in the absence of alternatives (e.g. access to affordable childcare). Gash
(2008: 658) observes that without accurate measures of preferences before outcome
and ex post, it is impossible to determine whether preferences determine outcome
or whether preferences shift to reect outcome. She suggests that, given the consider-
able risk of reverse causation in preference formation, preferences should only be used
as causal explanation of outcome if it is clear that they have not been affected by out-
come (Gash, 2008: 669). Gash concludes that preferences are weak predictors of
worker outcomes, but that market rigidities and family care responsibilities are likely
to impede working-preference attainmentcontingent on national context, policies
and practices supportive (or otherwise) of maternal employment.
404 Sian Moore, et al.
© 2018 Brian Towers (BRITOW) and John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT