Exploring the gender difference in multiple job holding

AuthorAlison Preston,Robert E. Wright
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/irj.12300
Published date01 July 2020
Date01 July 2020
Exploring the gender difference in multiple
job holding
Alison Preston*and Robert E. Wright
ABSTRACT
This article examines the determinants of the gender gap in multiple job holding in
Australia using all 18 waves (20012018) of the Household, Income and Labour
Dynamics in Australia (HILDA) survey. In Australia, like most high-income coun-
tries, the multiple job holding rate is higher for women compared with men. The em-
pirical analysis focuses on the role played by factors such as wage rates, hours
worked, household wealth, job security, education, demographics and demand condi-
tions. Probit regressions point to a large, negative and highly statistically signicant
effect of hours worked in the primary job on the probability of holding a secondary
job. This effect is larger (more negative) for women. A decomposition analysis sug-
gests that a large share of gender gap in multiple job holding (c. 90 per cent) may
be attributed to the gender gap in the hours worked in the primary job. Regulation
concerning working time can be expected to affect multiple job holding rates.
1 INTRODUCTION
Over the past two decades, there has been signicant change in the organisation and
regulation of working time in most high-income countries. In a number of countries
(including Australia and the UK), reforms have led to an expansion of what may
be termed non-standard employment. This includes the rise in the numbers
employed in casual, temporary and non-permanent contract jobs (Campbell, 2018;
Lab and Wooden, 2020; Rubery et al., 2005). There has also been an increase in
the numbers employed on a part-time basis who would prefer to work more hours
a form of underemployment(Birch and Preston, 2020; Koumenta and Wil-
liams, 2019). Understanding the causes and consequences of non-standard employ-
ment is of considerable interest in industrial relations and labour economics. Some
have focused on the role played by supply-side factors in non-standard employment
decisions, such as preferences and choice (Taylor, 2017). Others have considered
demand-side factors, such as employer-led exibility and non-pecuniary benets
(Briken and Taylor, 2018; Koumenta and Williams, 2019; Moore et al., 2018; Rubery
et al., 2005; Rubery et al., 2015). Clearly, given the growth in non-standard
employment, research of this type is both needed and important.
Alison Preston, Department of Economics, UWA Business School, University of Western Australia,
Crawley, WA Australia and Robert E. Wright, Adam Smith Business School, University of Glasgow,
Glasgow, UK. Correspondence should be addressed to Professor Alison Preston, Department of
Economics, UWA Business School, University of Western Australia, 35 Stirling Hwy, Crawley, WA
6009, Australia; email: alison.preston@uwa.edu.au
Industrial Relations Journal 51:4, 301328
ISSN 0019-8692
© 2020 Brian Towers (BRITOW) and John Wiley & Sons Ltd
Multiple job holding is the situation where an individual is employed concurrently
in two or more jobs. We believe that multiple job holding should be considered as a
further type of non-standard employment, despite attracting only limited attention
in this growing literature. This relative lack of interest is surprising because one might
expect multiple job holding to be systematically related to underemployment and
other forms of non-standard employment. We also believe that understanding the de-
terminants of multiple job holding is particularly relevant in the context of the re-
cently announced living hourscampaign (Felstead et al., 2020). Concern about
high levels of underemployment and unpredictable working time arrangements have
led to calls for employment contracts with a guaranteed minimum of 16 hours per
week. One would expect that if this guarantee became a legal requirement, it would
have an impact on employment decisions relating to multiple job holding.
In most countries, multiple job holding is not a niche activity. Empirical evidence
suggests that few multiple job holders have more than one additional job. Therefore,
it is common practice in the multiple job holding literature to use the terms primary
job(or rst job) and secondary job(or second job). It is usually the case that the
job with the most hours worked is assumed to be the primary job. However, it is also
possible to make the distinction between primary and secondary jobs based on hourly
wages (i.e. the job with the highest wage being the primary job) or weekly/monthly/
yearly earnings (i.e. the job with highest earnings in a given period being the primary
job). It is also important to note that both types of jobs may be waged employment
(employee) or self-employment or a combination of the two. This suggests that there
may be considerable diversity in the type of work that multiple job holders do in terms
of earnings, hours and job type.
To date, the majority of studies that have empirically examined the determinants of
multiple job holding are based in standard labour supply theory (see
Killingsworth, 2009). As discussed below in more detail, this theory suggests that there
are two main motives for multiple job holding (Conway and Kimmel, 1998). The rst is
anancial motive. The central premise is that the earnings from the primary job are
insufcient to meet individual, family or household needs. This may be caused by an
hours constraint, where workers are restricted in the number of hours they may work
in their primary job. It may also be caused by a low pay constraint, where workers are
paid an hourly wage (or salary) in their primary job that is too low. If a worker is
employed in a job characterised by low pay and/or low hours, one option is to take
on a secondary job as a way of increasing total earnings.
The second motive relates to non-pecuniary benetsassociated with multiple job
holding. This motive covers a range of factors not directly related to nancial
remuneration. For example, a secondary job may serve as a path to a new career that
is not possible via the primary job. A secondary job may also reduce the hardship
associated with losing ones primary job, especially if the hours in the secondary job
are exible upwards. It is important to note that it is possible that a secondary job is
a non-paying job. One reason people may take such jobs is that they derive direct
satisfaction from the work itself. This motive is quite different to the nancial motive,
where it is assumed that the main reason for working a secondary job is the increased
consumption that the additional earnings provide. While early studies tried to
distinguish the relative importance of the nancial and non-pecuniary benets
motives, current research tends to treat working for no payas volunteering, which
is now a distinct literature (Lup and Booth, 2019). More recent multiple job holding
research has focused on the effects of multiple job holding on career progression
302 Alison Preston and Robert E. Wright
© 2020 Brian Towers (BRITOW) and John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT