Does a long‐term orientation create value? Evidence from a regression discontinuity

Date01 September 2017
Published date01 September 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2629
AuthorCaroline Flammer,Pratima Bansal
Strategic Management Journal
Strat. Mgmt. J.,38: 1827–1847 (2017)
Published online EarlyView 7 February 2017 in WileyOnline Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com) DOI: 10.1002/smj.2629
Received 1 July 2015;Final revisionreceived 10 October 2016
DOES A LONG-TERM ORIENTATION CREATE VALUE?
EVIDENCE FROM A REGRESSION DISCONTINUITY
CAROLINE FLAMMER1*and PRATIMA BANSAL2
1Questrom School of Business, Boston University, Boston, Massachusetts, U.S.A.
2Ivey Business School, Western University,London Ontario, Canada
Research summary: In this paper, we theorize and empirically investigate how a long-term
orientation impacts rm value. To study this relationship, we exploit exogenous changes in
executives’ long-term incentives. Specically, we examine shareholder proposals on long-term
executive compensation that pass or fail by a small margin of votes. The passage of such “close
call” proposals is akin to a random assignment of long-term incentives and hence provides a
clean causal estimate. We nd that the adoption of such proposals leads to (1) an increase in
rm value and operating performance—suggesting that a long-term orientation is benecial to
companies—and (2) an increase in rms’ investments in long-term strategies such as innovation
and stakeholder relationships. Overall, our results are consistent with a “time-based” agency
conict between shareholders and managers.
Managerial summary: This paper shows that corporate short-termism is hampering business
success. We show clear, causal evidence that imposing long-term incentives on executives—in the
form of long-term executive compensation—improves businessperformance. Long-term executive
compensation includes restricted stocks, restricted stock options, and long-term incentive plans.
Firms that adopted shareholder resolutionson long-term compensation experienced a signicant
increase in their stock price. This stock price increase foreshadowed an increase in operating
prots that materialized after twoyears. We unpack the reasons for these improvements in
performance, and nd that rms that adopted these shareholderresolutions made more investments
in R&D and stakeholder engagement, especially pertaining to employees and the natural
environment. Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
INTRODUCTION
Agency theory argues that managers’ preferences
are misaligned with those of the shareholders. As
a result, managers invest in projects that are not
the rst-best from the shareholders’ perspective,
leading to a decrease in rm value. Traditional
agency models focus on managers’ preference
Keywords: long-term orientation; nancial performance;
innovation; stakeholder relations; agency theory; regres-
sion discontinuity
*Correspondence to: Caroline Flammer, Questrom School of
Business, Boston University,595 Commonwealth Avenue, Ofce
634A, Boston, MA 02215, U.S.A. E-mail: cammer@bu.edu
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
for, e.g., empire building (e.g., Jensen, 1986),
shirking (e.g., Bertrand and Mullainathan, 2003;
Holmstrom, 1979), or too little risk taking (e.g.,
Gormley and Matsa, 2016; Holmstrom, 1999).
In contrast, the question of whether companies
face a time-based agency problem— i.e., whether
managers’ time preferences are misaligned with
those of the shareholders— remains to be explored.
In this article, we aim to ll this void. Speci-
cally, we explore whether managers have a higher
discount rate— that is, a preference for the short
term— relative to shareholders. Anecdotal evidence
suggests that this might be the case. Indeed, a large
number of companies focus on meeting short-term
goals, even if doing so hinders the pursuit of
1828 C. Flammer and P. Bansal
superior long-term projects. Perhaps the most
striking evidence is provided in a survey by Gra-
ham, Harvey, and Rajgopal (2005), who nd that
78 percent of the surveyed executives would sacri-
ce projects with positive net present value (NPV)
if adopting them resulted in the rm missing quar-
terly earnings expectations. Overall, this evidence
is suggestive of a time-based agency problem.
If managers are myopic, we expect that the adop-
tion of a longer-term orientation (e.g., through the
provision of long-term incentives to the managers)
increases rm value. In other words, by adopting
longer time horizons, companies are able to coun-
teract managerial myopia and hence align man-
agers’ interests with long-term value creation.
From an empirical perspective, it is difcult to
examine the effect of a long-term orientation on
rm performance. There are two main obstacles.
First, temporal orientation is inherently unob-
servable. Second, temporal orientation is likely
endogenous with respect to nancial performance,
which makes it difcult to establish causality. For
example, nding a positive correlation between
empirical measures of long-term orientation and
performance may be driven by “deep pockets”:
companies that perform better need to worry less
about the short run and hence can more easily
afford to be long-term oriented. Similarly, the
relationship between a long-term orientation and
rm performance may be spurious if it is driven
by omitted variables. This concern is particu-
larly severe given that unobservable rm-level
attributes— such as managerial ability, investment
opportunities, etc.— are likely to drive both a
rm’s long-term orientation and performance.
In a nutshell, while empirically challenging,
exploiting a research design that provides a clean
causal estimate is essential to understanding the
impact of companies’ temporal orientation on
performance.
In this study, we attempt to overcome both obsta-
cles. Specically, we exploit a quasi-natural exper-
iment provided by exogenous changes in long-term
executivecompensation. The objective of long-term
executive compensation is to focus executives’
effort on creating long-term value, thus fostering
organizational long-term orientation (e.g., Cheng,
2004; Kole, 1997). Toobtain exogenous changes in
long-term compensation, we examine shareholder
proposals advocating the use of long-term execu-
tive compensation that pass or fail by a small mar-
gin of votes at shareholder meetings. Intuitively,
there should be no systematic difference between
companies that marginally pass long-term compen-
sation proposals with, say, 50.1percent of the votes
and companies that reject comparable proposals
with 49.9 percent of the votes. The passage of such
“close call” proposals is akin to a random assign-
ment of long-term incentives to companies and
therefore provides a quasi-experimental setting to
measure the causal effect of a long-term orientation
on rm performance. In the economics literature,
this approach of comparing outcomes just above
and below a discontinuous threshold is known as
“regression discontinuity design” (RDD). In this
article, the discontinuity arises because a minor dif-
ference in vote shares around the majority threshold
leads to a discrete change (that is, a discontinuity) in
the adoption of long-term compensation policies.1
Using this RDD approach, we nd that the pas-
sage of long-term compensation proposals leads to
a signicant increase in shareholder value. In par-
ticular, on the day of the shareholder meeting, a
proposal that marginally passes yields an abnor-
mal return of 1.14 percent compared to a proposal
that is marginally rejected. This evidence is con-
sistent with the view that a long-term orientation is
value-enhancing.
We further examine the effect of passing
long-term incentive proposals on operating perfor-
mance. Specically, we consider three measures
of operating performance (return on assets, net
prot margin, and sales growth). Regardless of the
measure, we consistently nd that operating per-
formance increases in the long run. Interestingly,
operating performance decreases slightly in the
short run (i.e., in the year following the vote), indi-
cating that an increased long-term orientation may
take some time to materialize into higher prots.
Arguably, this evidence suggests that managers
channel more resources toward long-term projects
that are costly in the short run, but pay off in the
long run.
To further explore this mechanism, we exam-
ine directly whether companies adopting long-term
compensation proposals are more likely to increase
their investments in long-term strategies such as
innovation and stakeholder relationships. We nd
1For a survey of RDD applications, see Lee and Lemieux (2010).
The RDD methodology is often seen as the sharpest tool of causal
inference since it approximates very closely the ideal setting of
randomized control experiments (see Lee and Lemieux, 2010:
282).
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,38: 1827–1847 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/smj

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT