Corporate governance antecedents to shareholder activism: A zero‐inflated process

AuthorMaria Goranova,Ehsan S. Soofi,Rahi Abouk,Paul C. Nystrom
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2472
Date01 February 2017
Published date01 February 2017
Strategic Management Journal
Strat. Mgmt. J.,38: 415–435 (2017)
Published online EarlyView 9 February 2016 in WileyOnline Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com) DOI: 10.1002/smj.2472
Received 29 October 2013;Final revision received29 September 2015
CORPORATE GOVERNANCE ANTECEDENTS TO
SHAREHOLDER ACTIVISM: A ZERO-INFLATED
PROCESS
MARIA GORANOVA,1*RAHI ABOUK,2PAUL C. NYSTROM,1and EHSAN S.
SOOFI1
1Sheldon B. Lubar School of Business, University of Wisconsin-Milwaukee,
Milwaukee, Wisconsin, U.S.A.
2Department of Economics, Finance, and Global Business, Cotsakos College of
Business, William Paterson University, Wayne, New Jersey, U.S.A.
Research summary: Shareholder activism has become morewidespread, yet the role of corporate
governance as antecedent to shareholder activism remains equivocal. We propose a new concep-
tual model that characterizes the stochastic of observable shareholder activism as a compound
product of two latent components representing (1) shareholder activists’ propensity to target a
company and (2) executives’ propensityto settle activists’ demands privately. Our model explicitly
decouples corporate governance expectations for the two latent components embedded in activism
process, and thus allows us to relax assumptions of homogenous shareholder interests and con-
strained managerial discretion wherecorporate managers are expected to negotiate privately and
settle only value-creating activist demands. Bayesian analysis of zero-inated Poisson regression
reveals that corporate governance relationships with activism vary across shareholder demands
and private settlements.
Managerial summary: Increasing shareholder activism has generated debates as to whether
activism promotesmanagerial accountability and responsibility or instead encourages managerial
short-termism. Our research model allows for heterogeneous interests among a company’s share-
holders. We theorize and empirically investigate a broader role of corporate governance: gover-
nance mechanisms need to ensure that executives are not (1) ignoring activists’ value-increasing
demands or (2) accommodating activists’ value-decreasing demands in a private, opaque manner
that disenfranchises other shareholders. Our results indicate that corporategovernance implica-
tions differ for visible shareholder demands in contrast with private activism. A plausible appli-
cation of our model is that it provides estimates of the probability of the numbers of shareholder
demands to be received by a rm and the probability of privately settling a demand. Copyright ©
2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
INTRODUCTION
Shareholder activism has rapidly changed how
corporate America thinks” (Solomon, 2014:1).
Studies have examined the impact of shareholder
Keywords: shareholder activism; corporate governance;
agency theory; Bayesian analysis; zero-inated model
*Correspondence to: Maria Goranova, Sheldon B. Lubar School
of Business, University of Wisconsin Milwaukee,3202 N. Mary-
land Ave., Milwaukee,WI 53201, U.S.A.
E-mail: goranova@uwm.edu
Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
activism on a broad range of organizational
practices and outcomes, such as establishment
of investor relations ofces (Rao and Sivakumar,
1999), utilization of ethics codes (Stevens et al.,
2005), executive compensation (Chowdhury and
Wang, 2009), environmental policies (Reid and
Toffel, 2009), R&D (David, Hitt, and Gimeno,
2001), and corporate social performance (David,
Bloom, and Hillman, 2007; Neubaum and Zahra,
2006). Corporate managers face escalating and
diverse shareholder demands for improvements in
416 M. Goranova et al
rm performance and corporate governance (Gillan
and Starks, 2007; Westphal and Bednar, 2008),
asset restructuring and cash distributions to rm’s
shareholders (Brav et al., 2008; Klein and Zur,
2011), and board representation (Gantchev, 2013).
Shareholder activists have also become more adept
in securing the support of other shareholders (Ren-
neboog and Szilagyi, 2011), extracting concessions
from targeted rms (Ertimur, Ferri, and Stubben,
2010; Thomas and Cotter, 2007), and forcing
CEO departures at companies such as Yahoo, J.C.
Penney, and Home Depot.
Shareholder activism has also generated con-
siderable controversy. Rising shareholder engage-
ment promises to hold corporations and their man-
agers more accountable (e.g., Bebchuk, 2005, 2013;
Daily, Dalton, and Cannella, 2003; SEC, 2010;
Waddock, 2004), but it has also attracted skeptical
voices (e.g., Lan and Heracleous, 2010; Stout, 2012;
Strine, 2014). Christensen and van Bever (2014)
call attention to the challenges faced by corpora-
tions when shareholders reward short-term actions
and strategies. Mayer (2013) worries that publicly
traded corporations have become a “rent extraction
vehicle for the shortest-term shareholders” (p. 240).
Such criticism raises the question about the role of
corporate governance in the context of shareholder
activism. Prior research posits that well-governed
rms will face more satised shareholders and
will be more accommodating to their demands
(e.g., Bizjak and Marquette, 1998; Cai and Walk-
ling, 2011; Gillan and Starks, 2007; Prevost and
Rao, 2000; Renneboog and Szilagyi, 2011). This
expectation implicitly assumes constraints on man-
agerial discretion that prevent self-serving man-
agers from negotiating with activists, as well as
homogenous shareholder activism that is invariably
value-promoting at the rm level. Can we equate
good corporate governance with implementation
of shareholder demands in those situations where
shareholders have heterogeneous or even conict-
ing interests (Connelly et al., 2010; Davis and Kim,
2007; Hoskisson et al., 2002; Tihanyi et al., 2003),
or where shareholders are “vulnerable to the same
forces of greed and self-interest widely understood
to face corporate ofcers and directors” (Anabtawi
and Stout, 2008: 1256)? Executives may sometimes
seek to “pacify” shareholders (Westphal and Bed-
nar, 2008), while protecting their discretion (David
et al., 2007) and managing their job risk (Neubaum
and Zahra, 2006). The current paper aims to address
this paradox and to extend our understanding of the
role of corporate governance in the context of share-
holder activism.
Weseek to contribute to the research on corporate
governance by answering calls for a broader con-
ceptualization of corporate governance (Starbuck,
2014; Tihanyi, Grafn, and George, 2014). Agency
theory has dominated governance research to such
an extent that Dalton and colleagues (2007: 42) state
the notion of agency theory and corporate gov-
ernance are essentially equivalent.” Activism liter-
ature has similarly adopted an agency-based view
of governance in which well-governed rms are
less burdened with agency costs and thereby less
likely to incite shareholder discontent and activism
(Bizjak and Marquette, 1998; Carleton, Nelson, and
Weisbach, 1998; Gillan and Starks, 2007; Ren-
neboog and Szilagyi, 2011). Equating good gov-
ernance with frictionless implementation of share-
holder demands (e.g., Azar, Schmalz, and Tecu,
2014), however, may be more problematic in sit-
uations where shareholder activism is not univer-
sally benecial for targeted rms or their sharehold-
ers (e.g., Ertimur et al., 2010; Thomas and Cotter,
2007). Prior research posits a range of motivations
behind shareholder activism. Some activists target
rms that perform poorly or practice poor gover-
nance (Bizjak and Marquette, 1998; Ertimur, Ferri,
and Muslu, 2011; Karpoff, Malatesta, and Walk-
ling, 1996). Other activists may be motivated by
factors unrelated to the focal rm, such as politi-
cal careers (Wahal, 1996; Woidtke, 2002), advanc-
ing the activist group’s visibility and consolidating
its identity (Rehbein, Waddock, and Graves, 2004;
Rowley and Moldoveanu, 2003), or attracting new
members (Agrawal, 2012).
Managers, furthermore, are hardly passive recip-
ients of shareholder discontent (Westphal and Bed-
nar, 2008). Executives sometimes face self-serving
considerations, such as career, jobs, professional
reputation, and monetary rewards, that encourage
them to be responsive to shareholder demands
(Neubaum and Zahra, 2006) or at least appear to be
so (David et al., 2007; Westphal and Zajac, 1994).
Prior research posits that behind-the-scenes share-
holder activism is widespread (Becht et al., 2009;
Carleton et al., 1998; Logsdon and Van Buren,
2009; Rubach and Sebora, 2009). Investors often
try to engage rms privately and then take public
measures only if private negotiationsfail (Gantchev,
2013; McCahery,Sautner, and Starks, 2015). Black-
rock, for example, states that it engaged with 1,500
companies in 2012, but “most observers are never
Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,38: 415–435 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/smj

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT