Competing technologies and industry evolution: The benefits of making mistakes in the flat panel display industry

AuthorJ. P. Eggers
Published date01 February 2014
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2129
Date01 February 2014
Strategic Management Journal
Strat. Mgmt. J.,35: 159– 178 (2014)
Published online EarlyView 19 April 2013 in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com) DOI: 10.1002/smj.2129
Received 22 November 2011;Final revision received 26 July 2012
COMPETING TECHNOLOGIES AND INDUSTRY
EVOLUTION: THE BENEFITS OF MAKING MISTAKES
IN THE FLAT PANEL DISPLAY INDUSTRY
J. P. EGGERS*
Department of Management and Organizations, Stern School of Business, New York
University, New York, New York, U.S.A.
This article investigates the post-entry implications of pre-entry technological choices made
during the uncertain period before a dominant design. Building on work on technological
dynamics and organizational inertia, I argue that too early commitments to the winning
technology may impede the ability to bring the best product to market, but delaying investment
too long limits the ability to accumulate useful knowledge. Using data from the evolution of
the flat panel display industry from 1965 to 2005, the study shows empirical support for the
two theoretical mechanisms and offers the surprising result that firms starting in the losing
technology before switching outperform other firms in terms of product value. Switching, while
difficult behaviorally in recovering from failure, both delays difficult-to-reverse technological
commitments and develops market knowledge. Copyright 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
INTRODUCTION
The early stages of a new industry are often uncer-
tain and convoluted, as firms explore potential
options. As a result, firms that commercialize the
same dominant design often follow different paths
to reach that point. Firms may transition not just
from the old technology to the new (Henderson
and Clark, 1990; Tushman and Anderson, 1986),
but also from one uncertain and speculative vari-
ant to another as they receive feedback about the
efficacy of their choices. We know relatively little
about the long-term implications of technological
choices made during the transition process, but
building blocks are available from prior work on
how inertia (e.g., Tripsas and Gavetti, 2000) and
Keywords: competing technologies; pre-entry experi-
ence; technological evolution; organizational inertia; flat
panel displays
*Correspondence to: J. P. Eggers, Department of Management
and Organizations, Stern School of Business, New York
University, 40 West Fourth St., Tisch715, New York, NY 10012,
U.S.A. E-mail: jeggers@stern.nyu.edu
Copyright 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
complementary assets (e.g., Tripsas, 1997) impede
or facilitate the transition from the old to the new
technology.
For industries that begin with competing tech-
nological options, managers effectively have four
options— support one technology or the other
or both, or delay until uncertainty is resolved
(Kretschmer, 2008). These choices may have path
dependent implications for long-term performance.
On one hand, firms initially focusing on the tech-
nology that later loses the competition are likely
to face internal resistance to switching to the win-
ning technology (Eggers, 2012). On the other hand,
firms making early investments in the subsequent
winning technology may do so too early and find
themselves unable to commercialize the best gen-
eration of the technology (Bohlmann, Golder, and
Mitra, 2002). Firms placing early bets on both
technologies might suffer the challenges facing one
or both types of focused firms. Finally, firms that
wait until the technological competition has been
settled may avoid making inefficient investments
but will not build important knowledge until after
160 J. P. Eggers
earlier investors, putting them at a disadvantage
(Cohen and Levinthal, 1990). These four state-
ments suggest that precommercialization choices
have significant implications for firm performance.
These idiosyncratic paths to commercialization
are a form of pre-entry experience (Helfat and
Lieberman, 2002; Klepper and Simons, 2000;
Sosa, 2013), as experience is accumulated before
commercialization (entry) and affects firm-level
heterogeneity in assets, capabilities, and knowl-
edge. Unlike recently studied types of pre-entry
experience, experience derived from early techno-
logical choices is not translated from a different
industry or submarket (de Figueiredo and Silver-
man, 2007; Mitchell, 1989), but is directly related
to the focal market and strategic choices made by
managers after the decision to pursue a new oppor-
tunity. As a result, firms may look similar at the
moment of commercialization (in terms of entry
timing and previous industry experience), but may
actually possess fundamentally different underly-
ing competences and resources. The difficulty in
navigating the uncertainty of an emerging new
technological space before the establishment of
the dominant design is an important subject, but
the effect of precommercialization choices is an
understudied aspect of competitive heterogeneity.
This study investigates the impact of precom-
mercialization technological choices on subse-
quent firm performance, focusing on the extent
to which these choices affect the ability to trans-
late technical knowledge into highly valued prod-
ucts. Using data from the inception of the global
flat panel display industry and tracking the evolu-
tion of two competing technologies— liquid crys-
tal (LCD) and plasma— from the 1960s through
the 2000s, this study investigates the product per-
formance implications of early knowledge creation
investments in the losing technology (plasma)
before commercializing the winning technology
(LCD). The results offer two interesting find-
ings. First, firms with greater precommercializa-
tion investment in plasma perform better in LCD
than firms that supported LCD from the begin-
ning. Early LCD supporters were able to develop
knowledge about the underlying technology, but
made a series of inefficient and difficult-to-reverse
investments in early LCD generations that did not
become the dominant design, and their reluctance
to abandon these investments hindered their abil-
ity to move effectively to the dominant design.
Second, firms that made significant early plasma
investments perform better in LCD than firms
that began investing in LCDs after the resolu-
tion of uncertainty, most likely due to knowledge
about market demands and expectations accumu-
lated from their early activities. Thus, in flat panel
displays, the data suggest that making a mistake
(e.g., the precommercialization choice to invest in
plasma) was a beneficial path.
This study makes three primary contributions.
First, the stylized fact of the superior performance
of firms switching from plasma to LCD in this
instance serves as an ‘existence proof’ that firms
making the wrong technological choice initially
can actually succeed in an emerging industry. This
perspective extends existing work on the impor-
tance of technological choices and organizational
flexibility in the face of technological uncertainty
(Bayus and Agarwal, 2007; Tegarden, Hatfield,
and Echols, 1999) and emphasizes that organiza-
tional adaptation is not just about switching from
the old technology to the new, but also about how
firms navigate uncertain technological transitions.
In doing so, this study adds an important facet
to our understanding of competing technologies in
new industries, where existing research has largely
focused on which technology wins (Arthur, 1989;
Schilling, 1998) and not on the firm-level implica-
tions of technological choices.
Second, I offer two theoretical mechanisms
that jointly explain the observed empirical out-
come. These mechanisms, rooted in the ‘win-
dow of opportunity’ model (Christensen, Su´
arez,
and Utterback, 1998), have broader implications
beyond the context of this study. One involves the
accumulation of knowledge applicable across tech-
nological platforms based on experience with any
technology in the industry. As the knowledge is
not tied to one specific technology, it is likely to
be market knowledge about consumer preferences
(Helfat and Raubitschek, 2000) that is related
to Sosa’s (2009) application-specific knowledge.
The other mechanism involves inertia resulting
from too early commitments to the eventual win-
ning technological option. Significant technolog-
ical investments typically result in routines and
processes that can be the source of inertia if the
commitments turn out to be suboptimal (Gilbert,
2005; Leonard-Barton, 1992).
Third, this study complements and extends ear-
lier work on technological competition (Eggers,
2012). Jointly, these works offer a more com-
plete view of the fate of firms making the wrong
Copyright 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,35: 159– 178 (2014)
DOI: 10.1002/smj

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT