Chapter VIII. Conflict, Convergence, Cooperation

Pages287-327
287
CHAPTER VIII
CONFLICT, CONVERGENCE, COOPERATION
A. Introduction
The preceding chapters touched on the approaches of non-U.S.
jurisdictions in certain specific areas of monopolization law, for purposes
of contrasting those approaches with that of the United States. This
chapter discusses in more detail—with a focus on case studies—the
complications that can arise when unilateral conduct of a dominant firm
is scrutinized by multiple jurisdictions, including differences in liability
rules, the potential for inconsistent remedies, and the tools, such as
comity, that agencies use to achieve greater convergence in the abuse of
dominance arena.1
Competition authorities generally agree that competition laws should
prevent firms with substantial market power from wielding that power to
harm competition. Beyond this general agreement, however, differences
abound.
At the most fundamental level, jurisdictions differ significantly in the
objectives they pursue in enforcing their unilateral conduct rules.2
Moreover, jurisdictions hold vastly different views regarding the level of
market share sufficient to trigger concerns regarding dominance, and
with respect to whether any—and if so, which—criteria beyond market
share are relevant in determining whether a firmis dominant. If a firm is
found to be dominant (akin to a finding of monopoly power in the United
States), even more significant cross-jurisdictional differences emerge
regarding the types of conduct that could be deemed to abuse this
dominance.
Experience demonstrates that these types of cross-jurisdictional
differences can generate inconsistent outcomes. Jurisdictions that
employ different substantive standards may reach varying conclusions
1. Additional issues may arise when the conduct of a dominant firm takes
place in more than one jurisdiction, including extraterritoriality and the
application of the Foreign Trade Antitrust Improvements Act. Both sets
of issues are outside the scope of this chapter.
2. See supra Chapter IV for more detail.
288 Monopolization and Dominance Handbook
with respect to whether certain practices are abusive and therefore
unlawful. Even when jurisdictions agree that practices are abusive, they
may disagree about appropriate remedies. Businesses may be able to
tailor certain practices or products to meet jurisdiction-specific
requirements; for those practices and products that are not “divisible,”
though, the jurisdiction with the strictest rules may dictate the global
standard. (In the alternative, multinational firms may be tempted to
cease doing business in the most restrictive jurisdictions.) Eventually,
when firms face tighter competition policies in other countries, they may
turn to their nations’ trade officials for recourse, transforming
competition issues into trade issues that may ignore consumer welfare
altogether.
To avoid these outcomes, competition authorities are continuing to
strive for harmonization and convergence. Competition authorities can
and do employ many bilateral and multilateral tools to increase
harmonization. At the bilateral level, countries enter into agreements
that provide for periodic consultations on competition policy issues and
for cooperation during the investigational and remedial stages of their
cases. By facilitating communication on policy issues as well as specific
matters, bilateral agreements encourage both procedural and substantive
harmonization. Similar opportunities for harmonization abound on the
multilateral scene, including through the International Competition
Network (ICN) and the Organization for Economic Cooperation and
Development (OECD). For a variety of reasons, it seems unlikely that
the World Trade Organization (WTO) is positioned to make significant
contributions to this process.
Attempting to harmonize competition policies and laws with respect
to unilateral conduct has been characterized as the “Mount Everest of
Antitrust.”3Even well-established competition regimes take divergent
paths in this area; relatively new competition regimes whose policies will
have a global impact (for example, in China and India) undoubtedly will
add additional layers of complexity to the task.
A brief review of harmonization and convergence in other areas of
competition policy, however, reveals that there may be reason for
cautious optimism. The international community has made noteworthy
3. Randolph Tritell, Dir., Office of Int’l Affairs, U.S. Fed. Trade Comm’n,
Introductory Remarks on the Objectives of Unilateral Conduct at the
Sixth Annual ICN Conference in Moscow (2007), available at
http://www.internationalcompetitionnetwork.org/uploads/library/doc395.
pdf.
Conflict, Convergence, Cooperation 289
strides toward convergence on the appropriate treatment of cartels and
toward harmonization on merger notification regimes. These strides
were made not overnight, but over a period of many years. Similarly, we
can expect that, if competition enforcers continue employing the
constructive tools at their disposal in the area of unilateral conduct, gains
in harmonization in other areas will be achieved.
This chapter first examines notable examples of divergence in the
area of unilateral conduct. It next provides an overview of the tools that
competition authorities have at their disposal to facilitate harmonization.
Finally, it examines developments in unilateral conduct policies from a
handful of jurisdictions to evaluate the prospects for convergence.
B. Conflicts and Inconsistencies in Enforcement Policy
Multijurisdictional abuse of dominance investigations occur less
frequently than do investigations of global mergers and cartels. For this
reason, there are fewer data points to examine when considering the
extent to which differences in unilateral conduct policies tend to have a
practical impact. The preceding chapters, particularly Chapters IV and
V, discuss the major areas of similarity and difference among major
jurisdictions in terms of types of conduct, remedies, and the like. In this
chapter, we examine a number of case studies of multijurisdictional
unilateral conduct enforcement proceedings. The first major case study
examined here is Microsoft, which has been subject to substantial
scrutiny in jurisdictions around the world, with significantly different
results, followed by Intel and Qualcomm, investigations that may lay the
foundation for future insights.
1. Microsoft
The Microsoft saga provides an excellent example of both the best
and the worst of multijurisdictional dominance investigations. Although
it began with closely coordinated investigations by the Antitrust Division
of the U.S. Department of Justice (Antitrust Division) and the European
Commission (EC) in 1994, it later devolved into a public clash between
the Antitrust Division and the competition authorities of two other
jurisdictions following divergent outcomes in their respective
investigations.4Long trapped in the crosshairs of competition authorities
4. Press Release, U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Assistant Attorney Gen. for
Antitrust, Thomas O. Barnett, Issues Statement on European Microsoft

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT