Chapter V. Specific Forms of Monopolizing Conduct: Controversial Issues

Pages135-211
135
CHAPTER V
SPECIFIC FORMS OF MONOPOLIZING CONDUCT:
CONTROVERSIAL ISSUES
Chapter IV examined the basic debate over the contours of Section
2’s conduct element. This chapter describes the legal standards applied
by courts, or suggested by commentators, for particular types of conduct.
A. Strategically Low Pricing
1. Predatory Pricing: Strategically Low Pricing Without Bundling
or Other Conditions Imposed on the Buyer
a. U.S. Law
In the United States, a lawful monopolist is free to charge as high a
price as it wishes.1Sometimes, however, a monopolist may choose, for
strategic reasons, to sell below the monopoly price. For example, a
monopolist with some competition may try to maximize its profits over
the medium or the long run by choosing to price lower than the short-run
monopoly price.2Moreover, a monopolist faced with potential
competition might choose, for the sake of maximizing long-run profits,
to adopt a “limit pricing” strategy—picking a price above the
competitive price but less than the monopoly price, which is more
profitable yet low enough to deter potential competitors from entering
the market.3Alternatively, a monopolist might choose to “invest” in a
predatory strategy, temporarilyselling its products for less than it costs to
make them in order to drive competitors from the market, cripple them,
or punish them severely for aggressive competition. Because such a
pricing strategy involves deliberate losses, it is not sustainable in the long
1. See Verizon Commc’ns v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, 540 U.S.
398, 407 (2004).
2. See 3B PHILLIP E. AREEDA &HERBERT HOVENKAMP,ANTITRUST LAW
722 (3d ed. 2008).
3. See id. ¶ 736b1.
136 Monopolization and Dominance Handbook
run, and makes economic sense only if the investment in predation can
later be recouped through future monopoly profits.4
It is, however, fundamental that “[c]utting prices in order to increase
business often is the very essence of competition.”5How should the
courts—giving due consideration to the public policies discussed in
Chapter IV.C.2.a—decide when strategically low pricing is
monopolizing conduct and when it is not?
Brooke Group,6decided by the Supreme Court in 1993, is the leading
case.7There the Court declared, “[t]hat below-cost pricing may impose
painful losses on its target is of no moment to the antitrust laws if
competition is not injured.”8By contrast, the “essence” of predatory
pricing—strategically low pricing as a form of prohibited conduct—is
that “[a] business rival has priced its products in an unfair manner with
an object to eliminate or retard competition and thereby gain and
exercise control over prices in the relevant market,”9that is to say, to
exercise monopoly power.
4. Matsushita Elec. Indus. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574, 588-89
(1986).
5. Id. at 594.
6. Brooke Grp. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209
(1993).
7. Brooke Group’s holding related to the standards of liability for
discriminatory predatory pricing in a case brought by a competitor of the
discriminating firm under the Robinson-Patman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 13(a).
But the Court observed that actionable injury to competitors under the
Robinson-Patman Act “is of the same general character as the injury
inflicted by predatory pricing schemes actionable under § 2 of the
Sherman Act.” Id. at 221. In LePage’s Inc. v. 3M Co., 324 F.3d 141, 151
(3d Cir. 2003), decided ten years after Brooke Group, the Third Circuit
asserted that “nothing in [Brooke Group] suggests that its discussion of
the issue is applicable to a monopolist with its unconstrained market
power.” Four years later, however, the Supreme Court noted that “[i]n
Brooke Group, we considered what a plaintiff must show in order to
succeed on a claim of predatory pricing under § 2 of the Sherman Act”
and that, “the standard adopted in Brooke Group applies to predatory-
pricing claims under § 2 of the Sherman Act.” Weyerhaeuser Co. v.
Ross-Simmons Hardwood Lumber Co., 549 U.S. 312, 319 (2007). See
also Pac. Bell Tel. Co. v. linkLine Commc’ns, 129 S. Ct. 1109, 1120
(2009).
8. Brooke Grp., 509 U.S. at 224.
9. Id. at 221.
Specific Forms of Monopolizing Conduct: Controversial Issues 137
The Court might have left things there, simply letting the trier of fact
determine, on a case-by-case basis, whether each challenged case of
strategically low pricing was likely to lead to monopoly power. But
history showed that allegations of predatory pricing were frequent, and
the Court was concerned that, without a more limited and specific
standard, legitimate price competition might be deterred. It reiterated an
earlier observation that “‘predatory pricing schemes are rarely tried, and
even more rarely successful,’”10 adding that “the costs of an erroneous
finding of liability are high . . . . It would be ironic indeed if the
standards for predatory pricing liability were so low that antitrust suits
themselves became a tool for keeping prices high.”11
Accordingly, Brooke Group established two necessary elements for a
predatory pricing claim. Reasoning that “[a]s a general rule, the
exclusionary effect of prices above a relevant measure of cost either
reflects the lower cost structure of the alleged predator, and so represents
competition on the merits, or is beyond the practical ability of a judicial
tribunal to control without courting intolerable risks of chilling legitimate
price-cutting,”12 the Court held, “[f]irst, a plaintiff seeking to establish
competitive injury resulting from a rival's low prices must prove that the
prices complained of are below an appropriate measure of its rival’s
costs.”13
The Court recognized that courts and commentators disagree on what
is the “appropriate” measure of cost but it declined to resolve the
question.14 It remains unresolved today, and it is the subject of much
discussion in the case law15 and commentary. 16
10. Id. at 226 (quoting Matsushit a Elec. Indus. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475
U.S. 574, 589 (1986)).
11. Id. at 226-27.
12. Id. at 223.
13. Id. at 222.
14. Id. at 222 n.1.
15. Most circuits have approved or adopted an average variable cost (AVC)
measure where prices below AVC will be deemed predatory, while prices
at or above AVC will be deemed non-predatory. See, e.g., Spirit Airlines
v. Northwest Airlines, 431 F.3d 917, 938 (6th Cir. 2005); Stearns Airport
Equip. Co. v. FMC Corp., 170 F.3d 518, 532 (5th Cir. 1999); Advo, Inc.
v. Philadelphia Newspapers, 51 F.3d 1191, 1198 (3d Cir. 1995); Tri-State
Rubbish v. Waste Mgmt., 998 F.2d 1073, 1080 (1st Cir. 1993); Kelco
Disposal v. Browning-Ferris Indus., 845 F.2d 404, 407 (2d Cir. 1988),
aff’d on other grounds, 492 U.S. 257 (1989); McGahee v. N. Propane
Gas Co., 858 F.2d 1487, 1496 (11th Cir. 1988) Henry v. Chloride, Inc.,

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT