Chapter VII. Settling State Antitrust Cases

Pages199-259
199
CHAPTER VII
SETTLING STATE ANTITRUST CASES
A. Introduction
In many antitrust cases, it is advisable for the litigants (both
defendants and enforcement authorities) to develop a settlement strategy
as part of their overall litigation strategy. The majority of antitrust cases
are resolved through settlement. One study found that more than 70
percent of antitrust cases brought by government agencies between 1973
and 1983 were resolved through settlement.1 A more recent study
estimated that 70 percent to 90 percent of cases brought by federal
enforcement agencies between 1987 and 1996 were resolved through
settlement.2 Understanding the settlement process, including both
strategic issues and the nuts and bolts of settlement agreements and
consent decrees, is thus crucially important for practitioners.
Settlement takes on added importance in antitrust cases because of
the heavy litigation burdens that antitrust cases impose on litigants and
because of the scale of treble antitrust damages. Trebling produces very
large damage awards and settlements. According to one study, the
average settlement or judgment in an antitrust multidistrict litigation case
between 1973 and 1984 was almost $90 million in 2007 dollars.3
Antitrust settlements and judgments in the hundreds of millions of
dollars are not at all uncommon today.
Settlement agreements, of course, are only partly about agreeing to
an amount of money to be paid by a defendant. Antitrust settlements
might also include ongoing limitations on the conduct of the defendant,
1. Jeffrey M. Perloff & Daniel L. Rubinfeld, Settlements in Private Antitrust
Litigation, in PRIVATE ANTITRUST LITIGATION 149, 163 (Lawrence J.
White ed., 1988).
2. See Lloyd C. Anderson, United States v. Microsoft: Antitrust Consent
Decrees and the Need for a Proper Scope of Judicial Review, 65
ANTITRUST L.J. 1, 4 (1996); see also Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep’t of Justice,
Workload Statistics FY 1997-2006 (2007), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/workstats.htm (stating current figures).
3. See Steven C. Salop & Lawrence J. White, Economic Analysis of Private
Antitrust Litigation, 74 GEO. L.J. 1001, 1009, 1012 (1986) (reporting a
figure of $44.5 million in 1984 dollars). Although the Salop & White
study is more than 20 years old, it remains the best large-scale,
quantitative analysis of antitrust litigation.
State Antitrust Enforcement Handbook
200
the impact of which can be significantly greater than the impact of the
monetary terms. Equally critical is the scope of the release negotiated,
including not only the claims released, but also the protections afforded
to officers, directors, and employees and the potential preclusive effect
on other plaintiffs. Finally, state attorneys general can issue settlement-
related press releases that might generate good will among constituents.
This chapter focuses on (1) some issues to consider when one
develops a settlement strategy, (2) the different forms that a defendant’s
settlement payments can take, (3) specific issues with respect to merger
consent decrees, (4) the process of obtaining court approval for a
settlement, and (5) the nuts and bolts of specific settlement provisions.
The chapter discusses fed eral law on many of these issues because
federal law tends to be more developed than state law and because most
states consider federal antitrust precedents persuasive. Indeed, many
state attorneys general bring enforcement actions in federal court to take
advantage of the Sherman and Clayton Acts. This chapter focuses
primarily on settlement of civil claims. State criminal antitrust
enforcement is discussed in Chapter IV.
Many of the settlement agreements referred to in this chapter are
available in the Settlements section of the Web site of the State
Enforcement Committee of the ABA Section of Antitrust Law.4
B. Strategic Considerations
1. Factors That Favor Settlement
a. The Time and Expense of Antitrust Litigation
According to one well-regarded study of antitrust litigation in the
federal courts, done by Steven C. Salop and Lawrence J. White, the
average multidistrict antitrust litigation between 1973 and 1983 lasted
approximately 5.7 years and had 968 docket entries per consolidated
case.5 Antitrust litigation remains lengthy and complex today. The study
also estimated that a large antitrust case generated, on average, legal fees
4. See http://www.abanet.org/antitrust/committees/state-antitrust [herein-
after State Enforcement Committee Web site]. The list of settlement
agreements on the State Enforcement Committee Web site sometimes
includes citations to decisions that approve the settlements.
5. See Salop & White, supra note 3, at 1009. One example of a particularly
protracted case is Matsushita Electric Industrial Co. v. Zenith Radio
Corp., 475 U.S. 574 (1986), in which 12 years elapsed between th e filing
Settlements
201
of over $800,000 in 2007 dollars.6 Given how much legal fees have
increased over the past 20 years, a significant antitrust case today will
routinely generate more than a million dollars in legal fees.
Indeed, the above figures might understate the time and expense of
antitrust litigation, because the data deal only with civil litigation in the
federal courts. Many defendants also face related investigative or
criminal proceedings and separate civil actions in state courts. To this
must be added the not-insignificant costs of economic and other experts,
whose involvement is almost mandatory in antitrust cases today. Finally,
the indirect costs to a defendant of executive time consumed by antitrust
litigation might well be on the same scale as direct legal fees.7
Avoiding the costs and burdens of litigation is a significant incentive
for the settlement of antitrust cases. This incentive applies not only to
defendants but also to antitrust enforcers, whose resources are often more
limited than those of large corporate defendants.8 On the other hand,
some states can and do retain outside counsel on contingent fees to
prosecute antitrust lawsuits.9
b. The Threat of Enormous Damages
The most powerful settlement incentive for an antitrust defendant
remains the sheer size of the potential damages in most antitrust cases.
The threat of treble damages, in particular, can create substantial
litigation risk even where a plaintiff’s clai m is weak. Some
commentators suggest that treble damages provide such a powerful
incentive to settle that parties bring weak, or even baseless, suits in the
hope of settling based on the potential damages exposure alone.10
of the original complaints and a decision by the Supreme Court that
upheld summary judgment for the defendants.
6. See Salop & White, supra note 3, at 1012-13 (stating a fee average of
$400,000 in 1984 dollars).
7. See Robert H. Lande, Are AntitrustTreble Damages Really Single
Damages?, 54 OHIO ST. L.J. 115, 142-43 (1993).
8. See 5 JULIAN O. VON KALINOWSKI ET AL., ANTITRUST LAWS AND TRADE
REGULATION § 96.01[1] (2007).
9. See, e.g., 15 ILL. COMP. STAT. ANN. 205/4b (authorizing retention of
private counsel); OHIO REV. CODE ANN. § 109.81 (same).
10. See Edward Cavanaugh, Detrebling Antitrust Damages: An Idea Whose
Time Has Come?, 61 TUL. L. REV. 777, 780 (1987).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT