Chapter 9. Potential Competition Doctrine

Pages321-346
321
CHAPTER 9
POTENTIAL COMPETITION DOCTRINE
The potential competition doctrine addresses the question of whether
a firm that is not currently competing in a market still has a
procompetitive influence on the market because of the firm’s potential
for entry. Underlying the doctrine is the belief that a market exhibiting
high prices and profits will attract entry by additional firms, causing
production to increase and prices and profits to fall toward a competitive
level. The presence of firms outside the market with the potential to
enter provides a present and/or future constraint on incumbent firms in a
noncompetitive market, as the incumbents seek to prevent or delay new
entry and respond to entry as it occurs.
In potential competition mergers, the potential entrant acquires (or is
acquired by) a significant market participant. Such entry by acquisition
eliminates the potential entrant as an independent entity that influences
or could influence the competitive performance of the market. As a
theory for challenging a merger, the potential competition doctrine
considers whether the elimination of the potential competitor as a
separate entity violates Section 7 of the Clayton Act by removing the
entity’s procompetitive influence. The potential competition doctrine
consists of two different theories: the “actual potential competition”
theory and the “perceived potential competition” theory.
The “actual potential competition” theory reasons that, but for the
merger with the significant market participant, the acquiring firm
actually would have entered the market either de novo or by acquiring a
very small or “toehold” incumbent firm, thereby creating additional
competition that would have deconcentrated the market or produced
other long-run procompetitive benefits.1 The merger with a significant
1.Though the maximum size of a toehold firm is the subject of some
debate, the Federal Trade Commission has stated that it is “desirable to
observe a general rule in potential competition cases that firms possessing
no more than 10 percent in a target market (where, as here, the 4-firm
concentration is approximately 60 percent or more) should ordinarily be
presumed to be toehold or foothold firms.” Budd Co., 86 F.T.C. 518, 582
(1975). Lower courts likewise have generally established the threshold at
or near 10% of the market. See United States v. Black & Decker Mfg.
Co., 430 F. Supp. 729, 767-68 (D. Md. 1976) (10% presumed a toehold,
firm with more than 10% not a toehold). But see Missouri Portland
322 MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS
market participant eliminates the possibility of de novo or toehold entry
by the potential entrant, and thus eliminates the possibility that the
market in the future will become as competitive as it otherwise might
have become if the potential competitor entered independently.2 Under
the actual potential competition theory, therefore, the injury to
competition is the loss of the procompetitive future effect that the
potential entrant would have had on the relevant market if the
independent entry had not been preempted by the merger.3
The perceived potential competition theory is based on the premise
that, if the current market participants perceive the presence of a
potential entrant on the fringe of the market, they will limit their prices
Cement Co. v. Cargill, Inc., 498 F.2d 851, 865 n.29 (2d Cir. 1974) (firm
with 10% of market is “probably too substantial” to be toehold
candidate); United States v. Phillips Petroleum Co., 367 F. Supp. 1226,
1258 (C.D. Cal. 1973) (“acquisition of a company which ranks seventh in
a concentrated market, holding a 6-7% share of the market, is simply not
small enough to constitute a mere foothold acquisition”), aff’d mem., 418
U.S. 906 (1974). The 1982 and 1984 Merger Guidelines, however,
establish the threshold at 5%. See U.S. DEPT OF JUSTICE , MERGER
GUIDELINES, 47 Fed. Reg. 28,493 (1982) § IV(A)(3)(d), reprinted in 4
Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,102; U.S. DEPT OF JUSTICE, MERGER
GUIDELINES, 49 Fed. Reg. 26,823 (1984) § 4.134 [hereinafter 1984
MERGER GUIDELINES], reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,103.
2.Underlying the actual potential competition theory is the assumption that
the addition of one more competitor to a concentrated market will
increase output and reduce prices. There is, however, only conflicting
empirical proof that market share and concentration are accurate
indicators of the likely competitive conditions in an industry.
Nonetheless, they remain the foundation of most merger analysis. There
has been significant debate in economics literature concerning the
empirical support for the existence of a relationship between the
structure, conduct, and performance of industries. For discussions and
summaries of the literature, see F. M. SCHERER & DAVID ROSS,
INDUSTRIAL MARKET STRUCTURE AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE 57-96
(3d ed. 1990); Richard Schmalensee, Inter-Industry Studies of Structure
and Performance, in 2 HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION 952-
1009 (Richard Schmalensee & Robert D. Willig, eds., 1989).
3.See, e.g., William J. Baer, Director, Bureau of Competition, FTC, Report
from the Bureau of Competition, Remarks Before the ABA Antitrust
Section, Spring Meeting 1999 (Apr. 15, 1999), at
www.ftcgov/speeches/other/baerspaba99.htm (“where the Commission is
trying to protect future competition, potential competition doctrine and
the use of innovation markets may be necessary for effective
enforcement”).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT