Chapter 10. Vertical Mergers

Pages347-369
347
CHAPTER 10
VERTICAL MERGERS
Certain mergers between firms participating in different but related
markets are termed “vertical mergers.” Historically, vertical merger
challenges have mostly involved firms at different levels of production or
distribution of a good or service,1 and vertical merger case law
accordingly tends to involve fact patterns in which there is a potential
customer-supplier relationship between the parties to the transaction at
issue. That relationship may involve two producers (one of which
supplies an input used in the production of the other’s product), a
producer and a distributor, or a combination of firms at different stages
of the distribution process.
The “vertical merger” moniker and analytical framework also have
been applied to a limited number of transactions in which the merging
firms supply products or services that are used by a single pool of
customers and potential customers. As discussed below, such
complementary-product mergers may present issues similar to those
presented by customer-supplier mergers.
Firms undertaking vertical mergers may happen to be direct
horizontal competitors in other markets, competing directly as alternative
suppliers of the same product or service. The competition issues arising
from the firms’ participation in markets that are adjacent to each other,
however, are the issues that give rise to the characterization of a merger
as vertical.2 By contrast, the “conglomerate” mergers discussed in the
1.See Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294 (1962) (“Economic
arrangements between companies standing in a customer-supplier
relationship are characterized as ‘vertical’”).
2.See, e.g., Brown Shoe, 370 U.S. at 323 (horizontal in shoe manufacturing
and vertical in shoe retailing); HTI Health Servs. v. Quorum Health
Group, 960 F. Supp. 1104, 1112 (S.D. Miss. 1997) (horizontal in certain
physician services and managed care markets and vertical in the acute
inpatient hospital services market); Harnischfeger Corp. v. Paccar, Inc.,
474 F. Supp. 1151, 1158 (E.D. Wis.) (horizontal in mine excavating
loaders and vertical in hydraulic crane winches), aff’d mem., 624 F.2d
1103 (7th Cir. 1979). See generally James R. Loftis III, How to Analyze
Dual Distribution Problems, in 2 ANTITRUST COUNSELING AND
LITIGATION TECHNIQUES § 11.02[3] (Julian O. von Kalinowski ed.,
1992).
348 MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS
next chapter involve firms that are neither direct competitors nor
competitors in adjacent markets.
When describing the firms involved in the customer-supplier type of
merger, the firm that provides inputs or operates at the earlier stage in the
production process is referred to as the “upstream” firm and the firm that
uses the input to make a product or is closer to the ultimate consumer is
called the “downstream” firm. A vertical merger may involve a
supplier’s integration “forward” toward the ultimate consumer, such as a
shoe manufacturer’s acquisition of a shoe retail chain3 or a Portland
cement producer’s acquisition of a ready-mix concrete company.4
Alternatively, the merger may involve a downstream firm’s integration
“backward” toward the supplier of an input, such as an automobile
manufacturer’s acquisition of a spark plug producer.5
In the complementary-product type of vertical merger, the two firms’
products are used in tandem, in either variable or fixed proportion. In
one example, the merging firms supplied electronic design automation
software used at different stages in the design of integrated circuits.
Although the products themselves were not substitutable, and neither
product was an input for the other, the firms’ software had to be
compatible so that customers could use the data output from one firm’s
software as data input for the other firm’s software.6
A. Historical Perceptions of Vertical Mergers
The antitrust treatment of vertical mergers tends to be fact specific,
with emphasis on whether a likelihood of harm to competition can be
demonstrated in the particular transaction at hand. Because the
analytical framework applied to vertical mergers has changed over time,
an understanding of the historical development of the legislative,
jurisprudential, and economic underpinnings of vertical merger law is
essential.
3.Brown Shoe, 370 U.S. at 323 (both parties were integrated manufacturers
and retailers, but Brown Shoe was primarily a manufacturer while Kinney
was primarily a retailer).
4.See Mississippi River Corp. v. FTC, 454 F.2d 1083 (8th Cir. 1972).
5.See Ford Motor Co. v. United States, 405 U.S. 562 (1972).
6.See Cadence Design Sys., 124 F.T.C. 131 (1997).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT