Chapter 4. Joint Ventures

Pages171-224
171
CHAPTER IV
JOINT VENTURES
In this chapter we examine the application of the antitrust laws to
joint ventures in telecommunications industries. The term “joint
venture” is vague, and often applied to a wide variety of business
practices. For this reason, we begin with a brief summary of the typical
forms of, and reasons for, joint ventures in telecommunications
industries. We then turn to the general treatment of joint ventures under
the antitrust laws, both by the courts and the relevant agencies, focusing
on the analytical framework for applying those laws. Finally, we
examine the specific treatment of actual telecommunications joint
ventures under the antitrust laws and the Communications Act.1
A. Types of Joint Ventures
1.
Joint Venture Characteristics in General
Joint ventures usually consist of two or more companies contributing
productive assets, technology, personnel or operations to an enterprise in
an effort to achieve efficiencies, speed innovation, enter new markets,
share costs, or spread risk. Joint ventures may lead to greater output and
lower prices, thereby increasing general welfare and benefiting
consumers.2 Although joint ventures partially align the economic
interests of the parent companies, they do so to a lesser extent than
mergers and acquisitions, which permanently fuse the merging parties’
interests. By limiting the level of integration between firms, joint
ventures can provide many of the efficiency-enhancing benefits of a
merger without eliminating all competition between the parties.
One difficulty with any analysis of joint ventures is that the term can
be used to describe a broad range of cooperative business arrangements,
1. Communications Act of 1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C. § 151, et. seq.
2. See, e.g., Northwest Wholesale Stationers, Inc. v. Pac. Stationery &
Printing Co., 472 U.S. 284, 295 (1985) (joint purchasing arrangement
“permits the participating retailers to achieve economies of scale in
both the purchase and warehousing of wholesale supplies”); SCFC
ILC, Inc. v. Visa USA, Inc., 36 F.3d 958, 963 (10th Cir. 1994)
(“efficiencies created by joint ventures are similar to those resulting
from mergers – risk-sharing, economies of scale, access to
complementary resources and the elimination of duplication and
waste”).
172 Telecom Antitrust Handbook
ranging from complex corporate structures to loosely formed, temporary
business “alliances.”3 A narrower definition would describe joint
ventures as having several of the following characteristics: formed by
parent firms that are not under common control; involving the partial
integration of certain operations of the parents; having a finite duration;
operated under the joint control of the parents; receiving a substantial
contribution from each parent; and existing as a legal entity separate
from the parents.4 For the purposes of this chapter, a joint venture will
describe an arrangement displaying most or all of these characteristics.
The potential benefit to consumers from joint ventures may be
realized even when the parent firms are actual or potential competitors.
In the continuum of cooperative arrangements between competing firms,
joint ventures have been analyzed as lying somewhere between cartels,
in which competitors coordinate their behavior without integrating their
operations (see chapter V), and mergers, in which competitors integrate
their entire operations, foreclosing all opportunity for competition
between them (see chapter II).5 Under this view, what distinguishes
lawful joint ventures from violations of Section 1 of the Sherman Act6
and Section 7 of the Clayton Act7 is the partial and temporary integration
of the parent firms that generates economic efficiencies benefiting
consumers without completely eliminating competition between the
parent firms.8 Thus, consumer benefits and limited integration are not
3. See, e.g., COMPACT v. Metro. Gov’t, 594 F. Supp. 1567, 1574 (M.D.
Tenn. 1984) (“Joint ventures present a difficult concept for antitrust
analysis, defying neat classification and precise definition and, by
extension, well established rules for evaluating their competitive
impact.”).
4. See Joseph F. Brodley, Joint Ventures and Antitrust Policy, 95 HARV.
L. REV. 1521, 1526 (1982).
5. See Thomas A. Piraino, A Proposed Antitrust Analysis of
Telecommunications Joint Ventures, 1997 WISC. L. REV. 639, 659, 663
(1997).
6. 15 U.S.C. § 1.
7. 15 U.S.C. § 12(b).
8. Piraino, supra, note 5, at 663; see also U.S. DEPT OF JUSTICE &
FEDERAL TRADE COMMN, ANTITRUST GUIDELINES FOR
COLLABORATIONS AMONG COMPETITORS § 1.3 (2000) (distinguishing
“competitor collaborations” from mergers since collaborations are of
limited scope and temporary, thus preserving some competition among
the parent entities), available at www.ftc.gov./05/2000/04/ftc
Joint Ventures 173
only principal characteristics of joint ventures, they may also be
justifications for their existence.
Joint ventures can focus on one or more stages in the production and
sale of a product or service. Upstream joint ventures may involve
research and development, or the purchase or production of an input.
They often enable collaboration in the development of new sources of
raw materials, technologies, or products, or the lowering of input prices.
Competitors or potential competitors involved in upstream joint ventures
may achieve these benefits while maintaining competition in downstream
markets.
Marketing and sales joint ventures may create efficiencies in
distribution in new geographic, product, or service markets. Through
marketing joint ventures, the parents may lower their costs by combining
marketing operations, increase sales of complementary goods and
services by offering them in a package, or increase “mind share” by
establishing a national trade name or service mark.
Fully integrated joint ventures encompass several upstream and
downstream aspects of a line of business, ranging from inputs to sales.
Such joint ventures may take advantage of efficiencies available only to
vertically integrated companies in new geographic, product, or service
markets that could not be obtained by the parent firms on their own.
2.
Types of Telecommunications Joint Ventures
The telecommunications industry has a number of characteristics that
often make joint ventures desirable as a matter of business strategy. The
infrastructure necessary to create a land-based, satellite or wireless
telecommunications network is large, complex and expensive.
Moreover, private and business consumers expect and demand constantly
improving and cheaper technology. To meet these demands, small and
large telecommunications companies alike have worked together in joint
ventures. Only with such cooperative undertakings have companies been
able to lay the undersea cables and launch national and global telephone
systems that serve the public today. A few examples are discussed here.
a. Upstream Joint Ventures
dojguidelines.pdf [hereinafter COMPETITION COLLABORATION
GUIDELINES].

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT