Chapter 2. Horizontal Mergers

Pages57-141
57
CHAPTER II
HORIZONTAL MERGERS
A. Introduction
This chapter examines the issues raised by mergers and acquisitions
involving actual or potential horizontal competitors. In the late 1990s
and early 2000s, the telecommunications industry experienced a wave of
horizontal transactions among firms seeking to expand their size and
scope. As used in this chapter, a transaction is “horizontal” if it involves
actual or potential direct competitors — firms that currently provide, or
plan to provide, the same kind of telecommunications products or
services. The term also includes mergers among firms that compete in
the same product market but in different geographic markets — for
example, two local exchange carriers that operate in different cities at the
time of the merger. For the sake of convenience, the chapter will use the
term “merger” expansively to include acquisitions of stock or assets.
Horizontal mergers have occurred among large and small providers
of a wide range of telecommunications-related services: local exchange
carriers; domestic and international long-distance companies; providers
of Internet services, including Internet backbone services; wireless
companies; and direct broadcast satellite companies. Most of these
mergers did not raise any significant competitive issues, and the
necessary government clearances were obtained relatively quickly and
easily. But antitrust and regulatory questions raised by the remaining
horizontal transactions have taken much time and energy to address.
State and federal antitrust laws, and state and federal laws regulating
telecommunications companies, generally seek to preserve a competitive
market. As a result, courts and regulatory agencies will carefully
scrutinize horizontal mergers that potentially create or enhance market
power. That danger may arise either because the merger gives the
merged firm unilateral market power, or because the merger makes it
easier for all of the remaining firms in the market to collude or cooperate.
Courts and agencies will also take a close look at any possible
competitive benefits from the merger, i.e., will the combined entity be
able to offer goods or services the separate entities could not offer?
Horizontal mergers may have vertical aspects as well. For example,
two horizontal competitors may each produce an input into another
market, and joining their productive resources may have vertical effects
in an adjacent market. The vertical aspects of mergers are considered in
Chapter III.
58 Telecom Antitrust Handbook
This chapter first provides an overview of the relevant laws,
including federal and state antitrust laws and communications laws
enforced by federal and state regulators. The chapter then examines how
these principles are applied by antitrust enforcers, regulators, and courts,
illustrating the issues with examples from horizontal merger cases of the
last few years. Finally, the chapter considers remedies that courts and
agencies may consider to address mergers that threaten to reduce
competition.
B. Overview of Legal Standards
1. Federal Antitrust Laws Governing Horizontal Mergers
Today, the bulk of merger review — and merger litigation — in the
United States is conducted by either the Antitrust Division of the U.S.
Department of Justice (DOJ) or the Federal Trade Commission (FTC),
which share jurisdiction over federal antitrust enforcement. The
analytical framework developed and applied by these federal antitrust
agencies has become the primary focus for merger review in general,
whether conducted by one of the agencies, by a state attorney general, or
by a court. It is helpful to review the statutory scheme underlying the
agencies’ analysis.
a. The Clayton Act
The antitrust review of mergers and acquisitions is primarily
governed by Section 7 of the Clayton Act.1 As a general proposition,
Section 7, a purely civil statute, prohibits any merger, stock acquisition
or asset acquisition in which the effect of the transaction may be to
“substantially lessen competition” or “tend to create a monopoly” “in any
line of commerce or in any activity affecting commerce in any section of
the country.”2
Today, there is broad agreement among the courts and agencies on
the basic principles of merger review under Section 7.3 This, however,
has not always been the case. Early Supreme Court cases focused on
1. 15 U.S.C. § 18.
2. Id.
3. See, e.g., Thomas B. Leary, Commissioner, Federal Trade Commission,
The Essential Stability of Merger Policy in the United States, Prepared
Remarks at Guidelines for Merger Remedies: Prospects and Principles,
Joint U.S./E.U. Conference (January 17, 2002), available at www.ftc.
gov/speeches/leary/learyuseu.htm.
Horizontal Mergers 59
hindering trends toward industry concentration in their initial stages, and
were largely grounded in a generalized “big is bad” philosophy. This
approach was replaced by the rise of the Chicago School’s rigorous
economic approach to antitrust analysis, with its focus on the
implications of mergers for prices, output, and, ultimately, consumer
well-being, as opposed to abstract notions of industry structure.4
The initial step in any Section 7 case is to define the relevant product
market (or, in the parlance of Section 7, “line of commerce”) and
geographic market (or “section of the country”) implicated by the
merger.5 How the court defines the market is one of the most essential
elements of the analysis, because how “substantially” a horizontal
merger affects competition will depend on which firms are deemed to be
“competitors.”6 Markets are defined from a consumer-driven viewpoint;
the fundamental question posed by market definition tests are to what
extent products and firms are substitutes for each other, and constrain
each others’ prices.7 The “product” component of this analysis focuses
on whether consumers faced with an increase in the price of a given
product can and will switch to another product which serves much the
same function; for example, if the price of Coca-Cola rises by a
relatively small amount, will consumers switch to Pepsi? If so (within
certain ranges), Coke and Pepsi are probably part of the same product
market.8 The “geographic” component of the analysis examines the
4. Subsequently, the Chicago School’s approaches and conclusions have
been subject to a variety of critiques. However, the approach resulting
from the Chicago School’s critique of earlier merger policy — grounding
merger review in economic theory, with consumer welfare as the primary
goal — remains dominant.
5. See 15 U.S.C. § 18; see also FTC v. Swedish Match, 131 F. Supp. 2d 151,
156 (D.D.C. 2000); FTC v. Staples, Inc., 970 F. Supp. 1066, 1073
(D.D.C. 1997).
6. See Swedish Match, 131 F. Supp. 2d at 156.
7. See id. at 157.
8. The general rule when determining a relevant product
market is that “the outer boundaries of a product market
are determined by the reasonable interchangeability of use
[by consumers] or the cross-elasticity of demand between
the product itself and substitutes for it.” Interchangeability
of use and cross-elasticity of demand look to the
availability of substitute commodities, i.e., whether there
are other products offered to consumers which are similar
in character or use to the product or products in question,
as well as how far buyers will go to substitute one
commodity for another. In other words, the general

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT