Board‐Level Employee Representation (BLER) and Firms’ Responses to Crisis

AuthorAleksandra Gregorič,Marc Steffen Rapp
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/irel.12241
Date01 July 2019
Published date01 July 2019
Board-Level Employee Representation (BLER)
and FirmsResponses to Crisis*
ALEKSANDRA GREGORI
C and MARC STEFFEN RAPP
Short: We hypothesize that companies with board-level employee representation
(BLER) experience a lower probability of crisis-induced dismissals than other
rms. Theoretically, we link this effect to the employee directorsability to
reduce the information asymmetry and moral hazard in employeeemployer con-
tracting, thereby facilitating the implementation of labor-cost adjustments that are
an alternative to workforce dismissals. We conrm our hypotheses by analyzing
the behavior of Scandinavian public corporations with/without employee directors
during the Great Recession.
...[t]he importance of the ability of employers and employees to
tackle shifting economic conditions was amply demonstrated during
the crisis when many employers worked with employees and their rep-
resentatives, in particular at the company level, to help keep compa-
nies aoat, reducing the need for job losses and helping to retain key
skills through, for instance, short-time working.(CEEMET 2012: 3)
JEL: L00, G3, J53.
*The authorsafliations are, respectively, Department of Strategy and Innovation, Copenhagen Business
School, Frederiksberg, Denmark. E-mail: ag.si@cbs.dk; and School of Business and Economics, Philipps-
Universit
at Marburg, Marburg, Germany and HHL Leipzig Graduate School of Management, Leipzig, Ger-
many. E-mail: msr@m-s-rapp.de. The authors would like to thank Ruth Aguilera, Morten Bennedsen, Gab-
riel Burdin, Ruediger Fahlenbrach, Marc Goergen, Takao Kato, Colin Mayer, and the seminar participants at
IZA Workshop on the Economics of Employee Representation: International Perspectives, Universita Auton-
oma de Barcelona, Brunel University, Gothenburg University, Utrecht University, Marburg Research Day,
ASSA meeting (Chicago), IAFEP Conference (Montevideo), and the Midwest Finance Association Meeting
(Chicago) for valuable comments and suggestions on this and earlier drafts of the paper. They are particu-
larly indebted to Evis Sinani for her help on earlier versions of this paper.
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS, DOI: 10.1111/irel.12241. Vol. 58, No. 3 (July 2019). ©2019 The Regents of the
Universit y of Calif ornia Published by Wiley Periodicals, Inc., 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA,
and 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford, OX4 2DQ, UK.
376
Introduction
The economic consequences of employee participation in corporate decision
making, particularly in the form of workersrepresentation on the board of
directors (board-level employee representation [BLER]), have been given quite
some attention in the academic literature (e.g., Addison and Schnabel 2011;
Fauver and Fuerst 2006; Gorton and Schmid 2004; Jones 1987; Svejnar 1981).
More recently, the public and academic debate about this characteristic of the
employeeemployer relationship has been gaining new momentum, with anec-
dotal evidence pointing to the relevance of employeeemployer cooperation
for swift adjustment to unfavorable economic conditions during the Great
Recession (CEEMET 2012; Glassner, Keune, and Marginson 2011; Svalund
et al. 2013).
1
This paper aims to contribute to this debate by analyzing the
association between BLER and rmsbehavior in the event of a negative
demand shock. Specically, we discuss theoretically, and analyze empirically,
whether employee representatives on the board of directors facilitated coopera-
tive rm-level labor costsadjustments during the Great Recession.
2
Across Europe, many companies presumably responded to the Great Reces-
sion by undertaking actions to reduce labor costs, from dismissals and early
retirements to more integrative solutions based on employeeemployer agree-
ments on internal redeployments, temporary working adjustments, and changes
in pay systems (Glassner, Keune, and Marginson 2011; Svalund et al. 2013).
Theoretically, when workers care about both wages and employment, as is
likely the case during an industry-wide shock or global crisis, integrative solu-
tions, which allow workers to trade a (temporary) reduction in their earnings
for employment, might be Pareto superior to unilateral employment reductions
(Aoki 1984; McDonald and Solow 1981). Bargaining over integrative (cooper-
ative) agreements is, however, subject to information asymmetries and moral
hazard problems (Aidt and Tzannatos 2002). The negotiation and implementa-
tion of such agreements might be therefore conditional on the existence of
mechanisms that facilitate the exchange of information between the parties,
1
Accordingly, in developed countries we observe a renewed interest in employee participation on the
board of directors. For example, recently the U.S. Senator Elizabeth Warren suggested that employees of
large U.S. rms should be allowed to send representatives to the boardroom. Similarly, during her campaign-
ing, Theresa May, the current British Prime Minister, contemplated providing British workers such an
option. See also Garnero (2018).
2
With the term cooperativewe refer to integrative solutions that should be preferable for both
employers and employees, thereby either increasing the benets of both or increasing the benets of one
party at no expense to the other. Such solutions might involve alternative measures of labor-cost savings in
the interest of preserving employment during a crisis (Aoki 1984; Glassner, Keune, and Marginson 2011;
McDonald and Solow 1981; Svalund et al. 2013). Note that we use the terms cooperative and integrative
interchangeably in this paper.
BLER and FirmsResponse to Crisis / 377
provide credibility for the information exchanged, and ensure an ex-post com-
mitment to the negotiated outcome (Freeman and Lazear 1995).
Employee representatives on the board of directors might constitute such a
mechanism (Aoki 1984; Freeman and Lazear 1995; Kochan and Osterman
1994). Given that they are elected by the employees and, as board members,
also accountable to the rm, these directors should be able to credibly transfer
information on the preferences of both employees and employers,
3
thereby
facilitating the information exchange necessary for integrative solutions (Aoki
1984; Freeman and Lazear 1995). Moreover, when employees participate in
the design of the rms policy, through their representatives on the board,
they will be less likely to renege on the reached agreements ex post by, for
example, adjusting their effort downward (McCain 1980; Mizrahi 2002).
Upon these arguments, in this paper we propose that companies with
employee representatives on their boards (BLER rms) should be better able
than other rms to negotiate alternative ways of reducing labor costs, such as
temporary furloughs, work sharing, and bonus restructuring, and consequently
less likely to reduce employment in the case of poor performance. We test
this hypothesis using a sample of 365 publicly listed nonnancial rms from
Denmark, Sweden, and Norway (Scandinavian countries) during the Great
Recession.
The Scandinavian setting is well suited to this study. First, workers in Scan-
dinavian rms employing at least (about) thirty employees have the possibility
but not an obligation to establish BLER. That is, employee directors are today
present only on the boards of companies whose employees or their representa-
tive unions, at some point in the past, exercised their codetermination rights
and demanded the implementation of BLER. Consequently, employee directors
are found in about half of the nonnancial publicly listed rms in our sample;
the fact that BLER is not implemented in all public corporations allows us to
draw inferences on the differences between the behavior of BLER rms and
comparable public corporations without employee directors. Moreover, the
BLER rights have been in place since the 1970s; accordingly, the BLER sta-
tuses of our sample rms have not changed since before the period of our
analysis, which mitigates reverse-causality concerns in our study. Second, as
did many other European rms (European Commission 2009; Gross and Acidi
2010), Scandinavian companies faced a substantial drop in consumer demand
during the Great Recession. In Sweden and Denmark, for instance, the demand
for manufacturing fell by 20 percent during 20082009, on average, demand-
ing substantial and swift reductions in labor costs (Svalund et al. 2013).
3
With the term employers we refer to shareholders or to managers representing the shareholders.
378 / ALEKSANDRA GREGORI
C AND MARC STEFFEN RAPP

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT