Why Do Politicians Intervene in Accounting Regulation? The Role of Ideology and Special Interests

Published date01 June 2020
AuthorJANNIS BISCHOF,CHRISTOPH J. SEXTROH,HOLGER DASKE
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1475-679X.12300
Date01 June 2020
DOI: 10.1111/1475-679X.12300
Journal of Accounting Research
Vol. 58 No. 3 June 2020
Printed in U.S.A.
Why Do Politicians Intervene
in Accounting Regulation? The Role
of Ideology and Special Interests
JANNIS BISCHOF ,HOLGER DASKE ,
AND CHRISTOPH J. SEXTROH
Received 21 May 2017; accepted 7 January 2020
ABSTRACT
Politicians frequently intervene in the regulation of financial accounting. Ev-
idence from the accounting literature shows that regulatory capture by spe-
cial interests helps explain these interventions. However, many accounting
rules have broad economic or social consequences, such as their effects on
University of Mannheim; Tilburg University.
Accepted by Philip Berger. We would like to thank an anonymous referee, Hui Chen,
Atif Ellahie, Dave Farber, Joachim Gassen, Sean Gerrish, J¨
org-Markus Hitz, Sebastian Hoff-
mann, Stephan Hollander, Wenquian Hu, Anya Kleymenova, Christian Laux, Robin Lit-
jens, David Maber, Mihir Mehta, Greg Miller, Catherine Shakespeare, Laurence Van Lent,
Johannes Voget, and Steve Young, as well as seminar participants at the 2016 AAA An-
nual Congress in New York, the 2017 EAA Annual Congress in Valencia, the 2016 EASYS
Workshop in Maastricht, the 2016 Lisbon Accounting Conference, the 2016 VHB Congress
in Munich, the 2017 Meeting of the VfS Ausschuss Unternehmensrechnung in Konstanz,
Erasmus University Rotterdam, Frankfurt School of Finance & Management, IESE, Lan-
caster University, Maastricht University, Sungkyunkwan University, University of Bristol, Uni-
versity of Exeter, University of Michigan, University of Paderborn, University of Zurich,
Tilburg University, WHU Otto Beisheim School of Management, and WWU M¨
unster for
helpful comments and discussions. We also thank Kirstin Becker, Johanna Busch, Piet
Mahler, Daniel Schreiber, and Matthias Uckert for excellent research assistance. Christoph
Sextroh gratefully acknowledges research funding from the Fritz Thyssen Foundation.
Jannis Bischof and Holger Daske gratefully acknowledge funding from the German Re-
search Foundation (DFG) under the CRC TRR 266 program (“Accounting for Trans-
parency”), Project-ID 403041268. An online appendix to this paper can be downloaded at
http://research.chicagobooth.edu/arc/journal-of-accounting-research/online-supplements.
589
C2020 The Authors. Journal of Accounting Research published by Wiley Periodicals, Inc. on behalf of The
Accounting Research Center at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business
This is an open access article under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial
License, which permits use, distribution and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is
properly cited and is not used for commercial purposes.
590 J.BISCHOF,H.DASKE,AND C.J.SEXTROH
income distribution or private sector subsidies. The perception of these con-
sequences varies with a politician’s ideology. Therefore, if accounting rules
produce those consequences, ideology plausibly spills over and explains a
politician’s stance on the technical accounting issue, beyond special inter-
est pressure. We use two prominent U.S. political debates about fair value
accounting and the expensing of employee stock options to disentangle the
role of ideology from special interest pressure. In both debates, ideology ex-
plains politicians’ involvement at exactly those points when the debate fo-
cuses on the economic consequences of accounting regulation (i.e., bank
bailouts and top management compensation). Once the debates focus on
more technical issues, connections to special interests remain the dominant
force.
JEL codes: G01; G28; K22; L51; M40; M41; M48; P16
Keywords: accounting regulation; fair value; financial crisis; ideology; polit-
ical economy; accounting standard setting; stock option expensing
This is a public policy issue. This is not an accounting issue.
Rep. David Dreier (R-Calif.), co-sponsor of a House bill on the
accounting for stock options (Spinner [2003]).
From the outset of the hearing, it seemed clear to me this was not going to be a
neutral discussion of the issues.
Robert H. Herz, former FASB Chairman, about the congressional hearing
on mark-to-market accounting in March 2009 (Herz [2013]).
1. Introduction
Although political forces arguably shape accounting standards (Zeff
[2005]), we know little about the motives behind politicians’ involvement
in the agenda setting or due process of standard setters (Gipper, Lom-
bardi, and Skinner [2013]). The accounting literature has predominantly
focused on the theory of regulatory capture, which explains politicians’
behavior as a response to special interest pressure from constituents and
donors (Stigler [1971], Peltzman [1976]). Evidence from accounting reg-
ulation is largely consistent with this view (Farber, Johnson, and Petroni
[2007], Ramanna [2008]). Political economy offers an additional expla-
nation, providing evidence that politicians’ ideologies can also influence
the political process (Kau and Rubin [1979], Kalt and Zupan [1984],
Poole and Rosenthal [1985, 1996], Levitt [1996], Mian, Sufi, and Trebbi
[2010]). So far, little evidence indicates what, if any, role political ideol-
ogy plays in the politics of accounting standard setting. The technical na-
ture of many financial accounting issues tends to mute ideological mo-
tivations: “Legislators and their staff typically know nothing, and could
not care less, about accounting standards” (Zeff [2010]). Put differently,
WHY DO POLITICIANS INTERVENE IN ACCOUNTING REGULATION?591
accounting rule-making is a “thin political market,” and the rules are gen-
erally determined by specialists (Ramanna [2015]), leaving little room for
ideology.1
However, many accounting rules have real economic or social conse-
quences. For example, bank accounting rules determine regulatory capi-
tal and thus affect the likelihood of regulatory interventions, such as the
use of taxpayers’ money for bank bailouts. Similarly, accounting rules for
stock option plans make different compensation schemes more or less at-
tractive and thus affect managerial compensation. Many of these economic
consequences are associated with ideological views (e.g., liberals prefer the
restriction of excessive top management compensation, while conservatives
oppose the spending of public resources on private sector bailouts). Ideo-
logical views on these economic consequences plausibly spill over to polit-
ical debates about accounting regulation, even if the accounting question
itself is not an obviously ideological one.
In this study, we investigate the public statements and sponsorship of
bills by U.S. legislators as a proxy for their involvement in two prominent
accounting debates. The first debate, concerning fair value accounting dur-
ing the 2008–2009 financial crisis, led to the relaxation of the FASB’s fair
value accounting rules in April 2009 (Herz [2013]). The change had direct
consequences for the regulatory capital adequacy of financial institutions
and thus affected the likelihood of bank bailouts and the transfer of tax-
payer resources to the financial industry. The second debate addresses the
expensing of stock options that firms grant to their employees and hap-
pened in 2003–2004, around the FASB’s adoption of SFAS 123. The ex-
pensing of employee stock options leads to the recognition of personnel
costs, potentially making stock option plans for top managers less attractive
for firms.
In both debates, the potential influence of special interest pressure
through political connections is evident. The relaxation of fair value write-
downs helps banks safeguard reported asset values against decreasing mar-
ket indicators and shield regulatory capital from corresponding declines
in equity. Other things being equal, violations of minimum capital require-
ments become less likely, as do costly interventions by prudential super-
visors, resulting in net benefits for bank shareholders (e.g., Bhat, Frankel,
and Martin [2011]). Similarly, any restriction on the expensing of employee
stock options helps avoid substantial reductions in the accounting earn-
ings of firms with extensive stock option plans, especially in the high-tech
1In this paper and in line with political science (e.g., Poole and Rosenthal [2011] and Mc-
Carty, Poole and Rosenthal [2013]), we use the term ideology to refer to a politician’sprefer-
ence regarding the role of government in the market. Even though this preference is located
on a continuum, we distinguish between a conservative (anti-government intervention) and a
liberal (pro-government intervention) ideology.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT