Why Do Countries Mandate Accrual Accounting for Tax Purposes?

AuthorMARTIN JACOB,IGOR GONCHAROV
Date01 December 2014
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1475-679X.12061
Published date01 December 2014
DOI: 10.1111/1475-679X.12061
Journal of Accounting Research
Vol. 52 No. 5 December 2014
Printed in U.S.A.
Why Do Countries Mandate Accrual
Accounting for Tax Purposes?
IGOR GONCHAROV
AND MARTIN JACOB
Received 17 July 2012; accepted 28 August 2014
ABSTRACT
This study investigates why countries mandate accruals in the definition of
corporate taxable income. Accruals alleviate timing and matching problems
in cash flows, which smoothes taxable income and thus better aligns it with
underlying economic performance. These accrual properties can be desir-
able in the tax setting as tax authorities seek more predictable corporate tax
revenues. However, they can also make tax revenues procyclical by increasing
the correlation between aggregate corporate tax revenues and aggregate eco-
nomic activity. Weargue that accruals shape the distribution of corporate tax
revenues, which leads regulators to incorporate accruals into the definition
of taxable income to balance the portfolio of government revenues and ex-
penditures. Using a sample of 26 OECD countries, we find support for several
theoretically motivated factors explaining the use of accruals in tax codes. We
Lancaster University Management School; WHU – Otto Beisheim School of Manage-
ment.
Accepted by Christian Leuz. We thank Johannes Becker,Dan Collins, Josh Coyne, Markus
Hitz, Ed Maydew, Erik Peek, Eddie Riedl, Doug Shackelford, Terry Shevlin, David Veen-
man, Kelly Wentland, two anonymous referees, and seminar participants at the University
of Goettingen, the University of North Carolina, the Erasmus University Rotterdam, the
WHU – Otto Beisheim School of Management, the Free University of Berlin, the 2012
American Accounting Association Annual Meeting, the Annual Congress of the European
Accounting Association, the German Academic Association for Business Research (VHB) An-
nual Meeting, and the Workshop on Current Research in Taxationfor helpful comments and
suggestions. We appreciate help from the local offices of Ernst & Young and KPMG, Wolf-
gang Zieren, Yutaro Murakami, Frederik Zimmer, Annette Alstadsæter, and Jan S¨
odersten in
obtaining information on tax rules. An online appendix to this paper can be downloaded at
http://research.chicagobooth.edu/arc/journal-of-accounting-research/online-supplements.
1127
Copyright C, University of Chicago on behalf of the Accounting Research Center,2014
1128 I.GONCHAROV AND M.JACOB
first provide evidence that corporate tax revenues are less volatile in high ac-
crual countries, but high accrual countries collect relatively higher (lower)
tax revenues when the corporate sector grows (contracts). Critically, we then
show that accruals and smoother tax revenues are favored by countries with
higher levels of government spending on public services and uncertain future
expenditures, while countries with procyclical other tax collections favor cash
rules and lower procyclicality of corporate tax revenues.
JEL codes: M41; H25; H21; M48
Keywords: accrual accounting; income smoothing; corporate tax revenues;
corporate tax base
1. Introduction
The role of accrual accounting in financial statements has long attracted
the interest of accounting researchers (Dechow [1994], Dechow, Kothari,
and Watts [1998]). However, accruals are also used in the country level
definition of corporate taxable income. For example, each corporate tax
code defines specific rules, different from either cash-based reporting or
financial accounting, for depreciating assets and for capitalization of re-
search and development (R&D) expenses. These accruals affect the time
when cash flows are reported as taxable income, reduce the volatility of
taxable income relative to cash flows, and thus better align taxable income
with underlying economic activity (Dechow [1994]). Previous theoretical
tax literature shows that defining taxable income on a cash basis or full
accrual basis leads to equitable and neutral taxation, while a definition
of taxable income that deviates from those two “extremes” can be distor-
tionary (Samuelson [1964], King [1975], Stiglitz [1976]). Nevertheless, tax
codes rarely define taxable income on a pure cash basis, or employ accrual
norms largely similar to U.S. GAAP or IFRS. Critically, there is consider-
able cross-country variation in the use of accruals in tax codes to define
taxable income. This paper examines the factors associated with this ob-
served heterogeneity in the accrual definition of corporate taxable income
to understand why countries mandate accrual accounting for tax purposes.
We hypothesize that the use of accruals in the definition of taxable in-
come affects the properties of corporate tax revenues and that countries
choose the desired level of accrual accounting that will balance the portfo-
lio of government revenues and expenditures. Prior research shows that the
definition of taxable income is a major determinant of corporate tax rev-
enues (Auerbach and Poterba [1987], Desai, Dyck, and Zingales [2007]).
Using accruals in the definition of taxable income can lead to lower volatil-
ity of aggregate corporate taxable income and, accordingly, also lower the
volatility of the resulting corporate tax revenues. This can be desirable for
tax purposes because stable tax revenues allow a country to maintain an ex-
isting volume and quality of government services (Groves and Kahn [1952],
Misiolek and Elder [1988]). Furthermore, accruals can simplify prediction
THE USE OF ACCRUAL ACCOUNTING FOR TAX PURPOSES 1129
of both future tax collections and government expenditures. This is of par-
ticular importance in the case of corporate tax revenues, which typically
represent the most volatile tax in governments’ portfolios (Felix [2008])
and average 3% (maximum 13%) of GDP in OECD countries.
However, the use of accrual accounting in the tax setting can present two
potential costs. First, accrual accounting requires judgment in estimating
income, leading to potential opportunistic discretion to manage taxable in-
come (Boynton, Dobbins, and Plesko [1992]). Such earnings management
can weaken the relationship between income and underlying economic ac-
tivity (Leuz, Nanda, and Wysocki [2003]). Second, the use of accrual ac-
counting in the tax setting can lead to undesirable outcomes even if accru-
als achieve their purported goal. By smoothing out transitory fluctuations
in cash flows and aligning taxable income with economic income, accru-
als may increase the correlation between aggregate corporate tax revenues
and economic activity (Guenther and Young [2000], Hanlon and Maydew
[2009]). This can lead to procyclical accrual-based taxable income: higher
tax revenues when the economy is booming, and reduced funds when the
economy is contracting (Lane [2003]).
We predict this trade-off between lower volatility and higher procyclical-
ity of corporate tax collections in high-accrual regimes as a primary deter-
minant explaining countries’ use of accruals for tax purposes.1Specifically,
whether a country chooses a more accrual-based tax regime depends on its
preference for smoothness and predictability of tax revenues over respon-
siveness of corporate tax revenues to economic shocks given a country’s
portfolio of government revenues and expenditures. That is, countries de-
fine taxable income to best fit their revenue and spending portfolio: coun-
tries with high uncertainty and higher volume of projected expenditures
are more likely to favor accrual norms that produce more predictable cor-
porate tax revenues. In contrast, those with more procyclical spending or
alternative revenue sources are more likely to rely on cash norms that lead
to lower procyclicality of corporate tax revenues.
We test this conjecture using a sample of 26 OECD countries over the
years 1997–2009. We construct a tax accrual index, which proxies for the
extent to which corporate taxable income deviates from cash accounting.
We then map the definition of taxable income in each country using ac-
crual norms required for major categories of fixed and current assets such
as capitalization of R&D and use of provisions.
Using this empirical proxy, we then assess whether accrual properties
affect a country’s choice to adopt a more accrual-based tax regime using
1There is anecdotal evidence that tax regulators face this trade-off. For example, the “Prin-
ciples of a High-Quality State Revenue System” promulgated by the U.S. National Conference
of State Legislatures (NCSL) states that a “high-quality revenue system produces revenue in a
reliable manner. Reliability involves stability, certainty, and sufficiency” (NCSL [2007]). While
lower volatility of revenues is desirable, the document acknowledges that some rules aimed to
decrease the volatility of tax revenues can increase their responsiveness to economic shocks.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT