When to haggle, when to hold firm? Lessons from the used‐car retail market

Published date01 July 2020
Date01 July 2020
AuthorGuofang Huang
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12385
J Econ Manage Strat. 2020;29:579604. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jems © 2020 Wiley Periodicals LLC
|
579
Received: 5 December 2017
|
Revised: 13 February 2020
|
Accepted: 25 May 2020
DOI: 10.1111/jems.12385
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
When to haggle, when to hold firm? Lessons from the
usedcar retail market
Guofang Huang
Krannert School of Management, Purdue
University, West Lafayette, Indiana
Correspondence
Guofang Huang, Krannert School of
Management, Purdue University,
403 W. State Street, West Lafayette,
IN 47907.
Email: huan1259@purdue.edu
Abstract
Though haggling has been the conventional way for auto retailers to sell cars,
the last two decades have witnessed the systematic adoption of nohaggle
prices by many large dealerships, including the largest newand usedcar
dealership chains. This paper develops a structural empirical model to estimate
sellers' profits under posted price and haggling, and investigates how market
conditions affect sellers' optimal pricing formats. The model incorporates a
simple class of bargaining mechanisms into a standard randomcoefficient
discretechoice model. With the extension, the productlevel demand system is
estimated using data with only list prices, and the unobserved price discounts
are also recovered in the estimation. The counterfactual experiments yield a
few interesting findings. First, dealers' adopted pricing formats seem superior
to the alternative ones. Second, dealers enjoying larger market power through
vertical differentiation and carrying a large number of models are more likely
to have posted price as their optimal pricing format.
1|INTRODUCTION
In the auto retail market, negotiation, or haggling, is the traditional way to reach a transaction price. The
conventional wisdom is that negotiation allows dealers to reap higher profits from consumers not interested in or
not good at negotiation and, at the same time, to get more business from the pricesensitive buyers. Yet, starting in
the early 1990s, some dealerships began to adopt hagglefree posted prices. For example, CarMax, founded by
Circuit City in 1993, sells mainly used cars at nohaggle prices. AutoNation, the largest newcarretailerinthe
United States, started experimenting with nohaggle pricing in its Denver stores in early 1999, and has recently
adopted nohaggle pricing throughout its stores. Many other large auto dealership chains have also converted to no
haggle pricing.
Why do some dealerships choose haggling while others choose posted prices? Are there conditions in which
onetypeofpricingformatwouldbefavored?Thispaperseeks to answer these important questions related to
pricing strategy in the car market. To address these questions, I estimate a structural model of demand and
supply using a new data set of car sales at five Baltimorearea dealerships. The model explicitly incorporates
sellers' pricing formats. I then use the estimated structural model to simulate and compare sellers' profits under
various pricing policies, and investigate the connection of the results with the sellers' competitive positions in the
market.
The above research strategy relies on two key steps. The first involves the ability to estimate the actual profits for all
dealerships. The second one is a consistently estimated demand system, from which the profits under alternative
pricing policies can be simulated. The main difficulty with implementing this approach is that I observe only the list
prices for cars and not the actual transaction prices, which is a common problem with aggregatelevel data in many
markets.
1
With the transaction price data missing, a direct application of the randomcoefficient discretechoice model
developed by Berry et al. (1995; hereafter referred to as BLP) would lead to inconsistent estimates, especially of the price
coefficient and actual profits. This is because it needs a more inelastic demand to justify the observed sales with the
observed list prices when some consumers actually were able to obtain discounts through negotiation. By explicitly
incorporating seller's pricing formats into the standard BLP model, I am able to correct the estimation bias due to the
missing data problem and recover the haggling dealers' unobserved pricenegotiation rules and, thus, the actual profits.
2
The data that I use in my estimation are constructed from the daily listing data from August 2008 to August 2009 of
five dealerships in a suburb of Baltimore, MD. I scraped the daily listing data from Cars.com, a leading automobile
classified website. Two of the five dealerships use the nohaggle pricing policy and the other three haggle. The listing
data include the list prices and detailed characteristics for all cars in the inventory of the five dealerships during the
period. I infer the sale date of a car as the date when the car's listing disappeared from the website,
3
and compute the
market shares by the car model and dealership for each quarter.
For estimation, I follow BLP and Petrin (2002) in using the Simulated Method of Moments to estimate the para-
meters in the structural demand model. My proposed pricenegotiation process has two dealerspecific structural
elements: the negotiation cost and price discount. The assumption I use to identify these additional parameters in the
structural model is that there is no unobserved heterogeneity across dealerships other than the unobserved discounts
and negotiation costs.
4
This assumption together with the existence of nonhaggling dealers in my data allows the
identification of the parameters in the negotiation process and in the buyer's utility function. Intuitively, the variations
in the market shares across car models sold by nonhaggling dealers identify the standard parameters in the buyer's
utility function; and, for a given model and the observed list prices, the difference in the market shares between the
haggling and nonhaggling dealers help identify the parameters in the pricenegotiation processes for the haggling
dealers.
Overall, the estimates show good face validity. The estimated unobserved discounts are of similar magnitudes to
those found in previous field experiments and in the actual buying experiences at the haggling dealerships. For the
mediumsized dealerships in my data, the estimates of their pricecost margins are close to the market average
pricecost margins that I derived using external sources of information. From the modeling perspective, my estimates
show that ignoring sellers' actual pricing policies and using list prices as the transaction prices in the estimation would
lead to significantly smaller magnitude for the estimates of the price coefficient and price elasticities.
For the empirical investigations of this paper, I find that, first, the relative performance of posted price and haggling
varies across dealerships. On the one hand, the dealerships using posted prices would see their profits increase only
slightly if they haggled, and the increase in profit could disappear if the haggling cost is accounted for. One the other
hand, the haggling dealerships' profits would drop significantly if they switched to posting prices. Second, I find that
market power derived from two sources, the vertical differentiation in qualities and the variety of models carried by a
dealership, has significant impact on dealerships' choices of pricing policies. In particular, sellers selling used cars with
rare qualities and/or carrying a large number of models are more likely to find posted price as their optimal pricing
format.
This paper is first related to the literature of pricing strategy in the auto retail market (e.g., Chen, Yang, &
Zhao, 2008; D'Haultfoeuille, Durrmeyer, & Février, 2019; Scott Morton, Zettelmeyer, & SilvaRisso, 2001,2003;
Sudhir, 2001; Zettelmeyer, Scott Morton, & SilvaRisso, 2006; and references thereon). This paper is distinguished from
the papers in this literature by its substantive focus on sellers' pricing format choices. In addition, this paper is also
different in its modeling approach that incorporates a simple negotiation structure into an aggregate demand system for
all the used cars in the market.
A closely related paper from the literature is D'Haultfoeuille et al. (2019), which faces the same methodological
challenge caused by the deviations of transaction prices from observed list prices when applying the BLP framework in
estimating the demand for new cars. Their paper obtains identification by exploiting supplyside optimality conditions
and focuses on showing the extent to which the price discounts vary by consumer characteristics. In contrast, my
identification approach exploits the existence of nonhaggling dealers in the market, and my substantive focus is on how
the relative performance of posted price and haggling for individual dealers depends on their competitive positions in
the local market.
This paper also relates to the empirical literature on bargaining and price discrimination, especially in the
automobile market (e.g., Ayres & Siegelman, 1995; Goldberg, 1996; Larsen, 2018; Scott Morton, SilvaRisso, &
Zettelmeyer, 2011). Papers in this literature show significant impact of bargaining on transaction prices and market
580
|
HUANG

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT