When the principal knows better than the agent: Subjective evaluations as an optimal disclosure mechanism

Published date01 November 2019
AuthorMengxi Zhang
Date01 November 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12297
Received: 9 July 2017
|
Revised: 15 July 2018
|
Accepted: 6 November 2018
DOI: 10.1111/jems.12297
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
When the principal knows better than the agent: Subjective
evaluations as an optimal disclosure mechanism
Mengxi Zhang
Institute for Microeconomics, University
of Bonn, Bonn, Germany
Correspondence
Mengxi Zhang, Institute for
Microeconomics, University of Bonn,
Lennéstraße 37, Bonn 53113, Germany.
Email: mzhang@uni-bonn.de
Abstract
When the firm has some private and unverifiable information about an
employees ability, it can design a subjective evaluation mechanism, whereby
payments are tied to evaluations, to communicate such information. In this
paper, I investigate how to design an optimal disclosure mechanism for the
firm. I characterize the firms optimal disclosure policy as a function of the
workers ability distribution, with the hazard rate function playing a key role.
I also demonstrate that with some reasonable restrictions on the ability
distribution, the firms optimal strategy exhibits a particular pattern: it will
reward the best workers aggressively, fire the worst ones, and assign one central
rating to the rest. The predictions are consistent with the way firms utilize
subjective evaluations in reality.
KEYWORDS
exante contracting, feedback credibility, information revelation, mechanism design, subjective
evaluation
JEL CLASSIFICATION
D21, D82, M50, J30, J41
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Consider a typical principalagent problem in which a firm hires a worker to work on a project. In classic agency
theory, it is often assumed that the agent (he) has private information about his ability in performing the task. The
principal (she) is less informed and thus needs to design a screening contract to elicit such information from the agent.
In reality, however, there are many circumstances where the principal is in a better position to evaluate the agents job
specific ability. This is especially likely to be true for workers who are new to the industry, who just got assigned to new
jobs, and who work in large teams. For instance, an experienced manager is likely to form a better judgment of a new
J Econ Manage Strat. 2019;28:631655. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jems © 2018 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
|
631
This paper is based on Chapter 1 of my dissertation submitted to Boston University. I owe my greatest debt to my advisors, Bart Lipman, Jawwad
Noor, Kevin Lang, and Dilip Mookherjee for their advice, support and guidance during various stages of writing this paper. I would like to thank a Co
Editor and two anonymous referees of this journal for very insightful and detailed comments. I am also grateful to Eddie Dekel, George Georgiadis,
Albert Ma, Michael Manove, Andy Newman, Juan Ortner, Joel Sobel, Ran Spiegler, and the participants at Boston University Microeconomic Theory
Workshop, 2014 CIREQ Conference, 2014 SEA Annual Meeting, CUHKDSE Departmental Research Seminar, Spring 2015 Midwest Economic
Theory Meeting, UNSW Economic Theory Workshop for helpful conversations and comments. Funding by the Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft
(DFG, German Research Foundation) through CRC TR 224 and by the Hausdorff Center for Mathematics are gratefully acknowledged. All remaining
errors are my own.
workers potential at this particular job than the worker. A supervisor, by nature of her job, usually knows more about a
workers value to a large team project than any individual worker.
Suppose, as illustrated above, the principal has some private and unverifiable information about the agents job
specific ability.
1
When the agents ability and effort are complementary inputs to production, the principal may be
willing to share some information to induce a better allocation of efforta more able agent will work harder if his
ability is credibly revealed. Since the principal has an incentive to overstate the agents ability to boost his motivation,
no useful information can be credibly communicated via cheap talk. However, the principal can design a subjective
evaluation mechanism, whereby payments are linked to evaluations, to convey information to the employee.
Intuitively, she can offer to make a higher payment whenever she claims the agent has higher ability. Then on one
hand, the principal is still tempted to overreport the agents ability to induce more effort; on the other hand, she also
wants to underreport to cut the cost. The tradeoff between these two concerns may make credible communication
feasible.
In the paper, I study the principals optimal information disclosure strategy in such environments. I also
demonstrate that my results can help understand the way firms utilize subjective evaluations in reality, which is often
at odds with standard agency theory. To be precise, the predictions of my model are consistent with the following
empirical regularities. First, many firms conduct subjective evaluations of their employees and yet assign very coarse
ratings to them. Second, the commonly used evaluation scheme is not only coarse, but usually takes a very specific
form. Indeed, most firms tend to assign one or two central ratings to the vast majority, frequently more than 90% of
workers. Only very few workers get ratings outside the central categories. This phenomenon is commonly referred to as
centrality bias.In a typical example given by Medoff and Abraham (1980), a large US manufacturer rated 95% of its
employees as either goodor superior,only 3.8% as excellentand 1.2% as satisfactory.
2
Third, although
subjective evaluations are frequently linked with payments, the corresponding reward structure is often highly skewed.
The highest rated workers are rewarded aggressively, the lowest rated ones are more likely to get laid off, and the rest of
the workers receive little or no pay differentiation (Zenger, 1992).
The model proposed in this paper dovetails with the longstanding view in the social psychology and human
resource management literature that firms use evaluations to provide feedback to workers. For instance, Cleveland,
Murphy and Williams (1989) surveyed 243 individuals who were employed at personnel departments or related
functions in private sector at the time of survey. They report that 53% of respondents perceived providing feedback to be
among the top three purposes of performance appraisals. The economic studies of subjective evaluations, in contrast,
predominantly focus on their direct incentive role (e.g., Baker, Gibbons & Murphy, 1994; Fuchs, 2007; Levin, 2003;
Macleod, 2003). The informational role of such evaluations, though also recognized (e.g., Milgrom & Roberts, 1992;
Prendergast, 2002), did not receive much attention in formal modeling until recently (Fuchs, 2015; Ray, 2007; Suvorov
& van de Ven, 2009; Zabojnik, 2014, etc.). Moreover, the study of optimal information disclosure in such circumstances
is largely missing from the literature.
3
This paper consists of two major parts. In the first part, I examine the theoretical question of designing an optimal
disclosure mechanism for the principal. In the second part, I use calibration to demonstrate that my results resonate
well with the empirical regularities discussed above.
In the theoretical part, I first characterize the set of all implementable disclosure policies and show that revealing all
information is always implementable. Second, I investigate optimal disclosure policies for the principal. Sharing
information always increases expected productivity by inducing a better allocation of effort, but may not be cost
effective for the principal when the agent is protected by limited liability. I start by considering the case where both
parties have nonbinding outside options and then extend the model to incorporate binding options. With nonbinding
outside options, I characterize the principals optimal disclosure policy as a function of the agents ability distribution.
The key factor is the hazard rate function. The principal finds it optimal to withhold information in the region where
the distribution has an increasing hazard rate (IHR); she may or may not reveal information in the region where the
hazard rate is decreasing, depending on the exact conditions. However, she will certainly reveal top states if the rate
decreases to zero at the top. So if the agents ability distribution has a monotone IHR (uniform, logistic, etc.), as often
assumed in the screening literature, then the principal chooses to withhold all the information. On the other hand, if
the distribution has a sufficiently long right tail (e.g., lognormal, Pareto), the principal always has an incentive to
separate the best workers from others. With binding outside options, the principal may find it optimal to fire the worker
if his ability turns out to be too low and she may want to withhold information from some intermediate workers to
retain them. Otherwise, the optimal disclosure policy can be characterized in the same way as in the previous case.
632
|
ZHANG

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT