What Is the Expected Return on a Stock?

Published date01 August 2019
AuthorCHRISTIAN WAGNER,IAN W. R. MARTIN
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12778
Date01 August 2019
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXIV, NO. 4 AUGUST 2019
What Is the Expected Return on a Stock?
IAN W. R. MARTIN and CHRISTIAN WAGNER
ABSTRACT
We derive a formula for the expected return on a stock in terms of the risk-neutral
variance of the market and the stock’s excess risk-neutral variance relative to that
of the average stock. These quantities can be computed from index and stock option
prices; the formula has no free parameters. The theory performs well empirically
both in and out of sample. Our results suggest that there is considerably more vari-
ation in expected returns, over time and across stocks, than has previously been
acknowledged.
IN THIS PAPER,WE DERIVE A NEW formula that expresses the expected return on
a stock in terms of the risk-neutral variance of the market, the risk-neutral
variance of the individual stock, and the value-weighted average of stocks’ risk-
neutral variance. Then we show that the formula performs well empirically.
The inputs to the formula—the three measures of risk-neutral variance—
are computed directly from option prices. As a result, our approach has some
distinctive features that separate it from more conventional approaches to the
cross section.
First, as it is based on current market prices rather than, say, accounting
information, it can in principle be implemented in real time. Nor does it require
that we use any historical information. It thus represents a parsimonious al-
ternative to pooling data on many firm characteristics (as, for instance, in
Lewellen (2015)).
Ian Martin is at the London School of Economics. Christian Wagner is at Copenhagen Busi-
ness School. We thank Harjoat Bhamra; John Campbell; Patrick Gagliardini; Christian Julliard;
Marcin Kacperczyk; Binying Liu; Dong Lou; Stefan Nagel (Editor); Christopher Polk; Tarun Ra-
madorai; Tyler Shumway; Paul Schneider; Andrea Tamoni;Fabio Trojani; Dimitri Vayanos; Tuomo
Vuolteenaho; participants at the Western Finance Association Meetings 2017, the 2017 Annual
Meeting of the Society for Economic Dynamics, the 2017 CEPR Spring Symposium, the BI-SHoF
Conference in Asset Pricing, the AP2-CFF Conference on Return Predictability, the 2016 IFSID
Conference on Derivatives, the 4nations Cup 2016; seminar participants at Arrowstreet, AQR,
Banca d’Italia, BlackRock, CEMFI, the European Central Bank, the London School of Economics,
MIT (Sloan), NHH Bergen, Norges Bank Investment Management, the University of Maryland,
the University of Michigan (Ross), and WU Vienna; and two anonymous referees for their com-
ments. Ian Martin is grateful for support from the Paul Woolley Centre and from the ERC under
Starting Grant 639744. Christian Wagner acknowledges support from the FRIC Center for Finan-
cial Frictions, grant no. DNRF102. We have read the Journal of Finance disclosure policy and have
no conflicts of interest to disclose.
This is an open access article under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License, which
permits use, distribution and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly
cited.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12778
C2019 The Authors. The Journal of Finance published by Wiley Periodicals, Inc. on behalf of
American Finance Association.
1887
1888 The Journal of Finance R
Second, our formula provides conditional forecasts at the level of the individ-
ual stock. Rather than asking, say, what the unconditional average expected
return is on a portfolio of small value stocks, we can ask, what is the expected
return on Apple, today?
Third, the formula makes specific quantitative predictions about the relation-
ship between expected returns and the three measures of risk-neutral variance.
It does not require estimation of any parameters. This can be contrasted with
factor models, in which both factor loadings and the factors themselves are esti-
mated from the data (with all of the associated concerns about data snooping).
There is a closer comparison with the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM),
which makes a specific prediction about the relationship between expected re-
turns and betas, but even the CAPM requires that the forward-looking betas
that come out of theory be estimated based on historical data.
Our approach does not have this deficiency and, as we will show, it performs
better empirically than the CAPM. But, like the CAPM, it requires that we
take a stance on the conditionally expected return on the market. We do so by
applying the results of Martin (2017), who argues that the risk-neutral variance
of the market provides a lower bound on the equity premium. In particular,
we exploit Martin’s more aggressive claim that, empirically, the lower bound
is approximately tight, so that risk-neutral variance directly measures the
equity premium. We also present results that avoid dependence on this claim,
however, by forecasting expected returns in excess of the market.Indoingso,
we isolate the purely cross-sectional predictions of our framework that are
independent from the market-timing issue of forecasting the equity premium.
As these predictions exploit the cross section as well as the time series, the
associated empirical results are stronger in a statistical sense than those of
Martin (2017).
We introduce the theoretical framework in Section I. We then show how to
construct the three risk-neutral variance measures, and discuss some of their
properties, in Section II.
Our main empirical results are presented in Section III. We test the frame-
work for S&P 100 and S&P 500 stocks at forecast horizons ranging from
1 month to 2 years. Papers in the predictability literature typically aim to
uncover variables that are statistically significant in forecasting regressions.
We share this goal, of course, but as our model makes predictions about the
quantitative relationship between expected returns and risk-neutral variances,
we hope also to find that the estimated coefficients on the predictor variables
are close to specific numbers that come out of the theory. For most specifica-
tions, we find that that we do not reject the model, whereas we reject the null
hypothesis of no predictability at the 6-month, 1-year, and 2-year horizons.
In Section IV, we examine how our findings relate to stock characteristics.
Notably, we run panel regressions of realized returns onto beta, size, book-to-
market, and past returns. In our sample, size and book-to-market are statisti-
cally significant forecasters of excess returns, though not of returns in excess
of the market. When we include our predictive variables based on risk-neutral
variance, these characteristics become statistically insignificant, but the
What Is the Expected Return on a Stock? 1889
risk-neutral variance variables themselves are significant predictors (of both
excess returns and excess-of-market returns). Moreover, they enter with coef-
ficients that are insignificantly different from those predicted by our theory. In
a similar vein, we show that returns on portfolios sorted on the characteristics
are consistent with the model.
In Section V, we assess the out-of-sample predictive performance of the for-
mula when its coefficients are constrained to equal the values implied by the
theory. We compute out-of-sample R2coefficients that compare the formula’s
predictions to those of a range of competitors, as in Goyal and Welch (2008).
We start by comparing against competitors that are themselves out-of-sample
predictors (in the sense of being based on a priori considerations, without in-
sample information). The formula outperforms all such competitors at horizons
of 3, 6, 12, and 24 months, both for expected returns and for expected returns
in excess of the market.
More ambitiously, we next compare the formula against competitors that
have in-sample information. At the 6- and 12-month horizons, the only case
in which our model of expected excess returns “loses” is when we allow the
competitor predictor to know both the in-sample average realized return across
stocks and the multivariate in-sample relationship between realized returns
and beta, size, book-to-market, and past returns. When we allow the competitor
to know only the in-sample average and the univariate relationship between
realized returns and any one of the characteristics, our formula outperforms.
Even more strikingly, in the case in which we forecast returns in excess of the
market, the formula outperforms the competitor armed with knowledge of the
in-sample average and of the multivariate relationship.
These empirical successes are particularly notable because the formula
makes some dramatic predictions about stock returns. Figure 1plots the time
series of expected excess returns, relative to the riskless asset and relative to
the market, for Apple and JPMorgan Chase & Co. over the period January
1996 to October 2014. According to our model, expected returns spiked for both
stocks during the depths of the financial crisis of 2008 to 2009. In the case of
Apple, this largely reflected a high market-wide equity premium rather than
an Apple-specific phenomenon, whereas JP Morgan Chase’s expected excess
return was high even relative to the market risk premium. The figure also
plots expected excess returns computed using the CAPM with 1-year rolling
historical betas and the equity premium computed from the SVIX index of Mar-
tin (2017), or fixed at 6%, to illustrate the point (which, as we will show, holds
more generally) that our model generates more volatility in expected returns,
both over time and in the cross section, than does the CAPM.
We conclude in Section VI. The Appendix contains a discussion of the rela-
tionship between our volatility measures and implied correlation, and provides
details of the bootstrap procedure. Finally,f urther empirical results and analy-
sis of the finite-sample properties of our block bootstrap procedure are provided
in an Internet Appendix.1
1The Internet Appendix may be found in the online version of this article.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT