What Drives Anomaly Returns?

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12876
Published date01 June 2020
Date01 June 2020
AuthorPAUL C. TETLOCK,LARS A. LOCHSTOER
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXV, NO. 3 JUNE 2020
What Drives Anomaly Returns?
LARS A. LOCHSTOER and PAUL C. TETLOCK
ABSTRACT
We decompose the returns of five well-known anomalies into cash flow and discount
rate news. Common patterns emerge across the five factor portfolios and their mean-
variance efficient (MVE) combination. Whereas discount rate news predominates in
market returns, systematic cash flow news drives the returns of anomaly portfolios
and their MVE combination with the market portfolio. Anomaly cash flow and dis-
count rate shocks are largely uncorrelated with market cash flow and discount rate
shocks and with business cycle fluctuations. These rich empirical patterns restrict the
joint dynamics of firm cash flows and the pricing kernel, thereby informing models of
stocks’ expected returns.
OVER THE PAST 30 YEARS, researchers have uncovered robust patterns in stock
returns that contradict classic asset pricing theories. A prominent example is
that value stocks outperform growth stocks, even though they are similarly
exposed to fluctuations in the overall stock market. To exploit such anomalies,
investors can form long-short portfolios (e.g., long value and short growth) with
high average returns and near-zero market risk. These long-short anomaly
portfolios are an important part of the mean-variance efficient (MVE) portfolio
and thus the stochastic discount factor (SDF). In the five-factor Fama and
French (2015) model, nonmarket factors account for 85% of the variance in the
model’s implied SDF.1
Researchers sharply disagree about the source of these nonmarket factors.
Several different models, both risk-based and behavioral, can explain why
Lochstoer is at the UCLA Anderson School of Management. Tetlock is at Columbia Business
School. We thank Jules van Binsbergen; John Campbell; Mikhail Chernov; James Choi; Zhi Da;
Kent Daniel; Francisco Gomes; Leonid Kogan; Stefan Nagel; Stijn van Nieuwerburgh; Christopher
Polk; Shri Santosh; Luis Viceira; Amir Yaron; an anonymous referee and associate editor; as well as
seminar participants at the AFA, Case Western,Columbia, Copenhagen Business School, Cornell,
FRB, LBS, McGill, Miami Behavioral Conference, Miami University, NBER LTAM, NY Fed, Ohio
State, Q-group, SFS Finance Cavalcade, Swedish House of Finance, UBC, UCLA, UC Irvine,
University of Massachusetts Amherst, and UVAfor helpful comments. Lochstoer and Tetlock have
no conflicts of interest to disclose.
Correspondence: Paul Tetlock, Columbia Business School, Department of Finance, 3022 Broad-
way, 811 Uris Hall, New York, NY 10027; e-mail: pt2238@columbia.edu.
This is an open access article under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License, which
permits use, distribution and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly
cited.
1Using data from 1963 to 2017, a regression of the MVE combination of the five Fama-French
factors on the market factor yields an R2of 15%.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12876
C2020 The Authors. The Journal of Finance published by Wiley Periodicals, Inc. on behalf of
American Finance Association
1417
1418 The Journal of Finance R
long-short portfolios based on valuation ratios and other characteristics earn
high average returns.2In this paper, we introduce an efficient empirical tech-
nique for decomposing anomaly portfolio returns, as well as their MVE combi-
nation, into cash flow (CF) and discount rate (DR) shocks (news) as in Campbell
(1991). These decompositions provide a wide array of new facts that can guide
specifications of asset pricing theories.
To see how this CF-DR decomposition relates to extant theories, consider at
one extreme the model of noise trader risk proposed by De Long et al. (1990). In
this model, firm CFs are constant, implying that all return variation arises from
changes in DRs. At the other extreme, consider the simplest form of the Capital
Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) in which firm betas, the market risk premium,
and the risk-free interest rate are constant. In this setting, expected returns
(DRs) are constant, which implies that all return variation arises from changes
in expected CFs. More generally, models that explain how firm characteristics
like book-to-market (BM) or investment are related to expected firm returns
have implications for the joint distribution of firm CFs and the pricing of these
CFs. Applying our empirical methodology to simulated data from any such
theory allows one to test whether the model matches the empirical properties
of CF and DR shocks to anomaly portfolios and their MVE combination.
Our empirical work focuses on the annual returns of five well-known
anomalies—value, size, profitability, investment, and momentum—from 1929
to 2017. We uncover three sets of novel findings for theories to explain. First,
for all five anomalies, CF news explains most (64% to 80%) of the variation in
anomaly returns. This finding builds on Cohen, Polk, and Vuolteenaho (2003,
2010; hereafter CPV), who show that CFs explain most of the variance in the
returns of the value anomaly. It also builds on Fama and French (1995), who
show that portfolios formed on size and value experience systematic shocks to
earnings. We find that such systematic earnings shocks occur not only in size
and value factor portfolios but also in profitability,investment, and momentum
portfolios. Moreover, unlike Fama and French (1995), we are able to explicitly
link systematic shocks to firms’ earnings to the returns of the anomaly portfo-
lios. Toevaluate implications for the SDF, we combine all five anomalies into an
MVE anomaly portfolio and continue to find that CF shocks explain most (73%)
of the MVE portfolio’s return variance. This finding contrasts with the stylized
fact that DR shocks explain most of market return variance (see, e.g., Camp-
bell (1991) and Cochrane (2011))—a fact that we replicate. The CF shock to
the anomaly MVE portfolio represents a large and common source of variation
in firms’ CF shocks that spans anomaly boundaries, which runs counter to the
conclusion in Vuolteenaho (2002; hereafter V02) that “cash-flow information is
largely firm specific” (p. 259).
Second, the CF and DR components in anomaly returns exhibit only
weak correlations with the corresponding components in market returns.
2See, for example, Barberis, Shleifer, and Vishny (1998); Berk, Green, and Naik (1999); Hong
and Stein (1999); Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Subrahmanyam (2001); Zhang (2005); Lettau and
Wach ter (2007); and Kogan and Papanikolaou (2013).
What Drives Anomaly Returns? 1419
Conceptually,there are four correlations of interest between anomaly and mar-
ket CF and DR components, all of which affect an anomaly’s market beta. The
correlations between market CFs and the five anomaly CFs range from 0.22
to 0.13. We can reject the hypothesis that CF shocks to the MVE portfolio that
consists of all five anomalies are positively correlated (above 0.11) with market
CF shocks, indicating that the anomaly MVE portfolio and the market portfolio
are exposed to distinct fundamental risks. In addition, we estimate that the
correlation between anomaly MVE DR news and market DR news is just 0.06
(SE =0.12).
Our third finding is that, for most anomalies, CF and DR shocks are neg-
atively correlated. That is, firms with negative news about future CFs tend
to experience persistent increases in DRs. This association contributes signif-
icantly to return variance in anomaly portfolios. A notable caveat is that this
result applies to anomaly portfolios based on stocks with market capitaliza-
tion not in the bottom quintile of New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) stocks,
which roughly corresponds to excluding stocks popularly known as microcaps.
In an alternative specification that includes microcaps, these stocks exert a
large influence on some findings because they are numerous and have volatile
characteristics and returns. Although our first two findings are essentially un-
changed in this alternative specification, the correlation between anomaly CF
and DR news abecomes positive.3
Our main findings cast doubt on three types of anomaly theories. First,
theories in which DR news is the primary source of anomaly returns, such as
De Long et al. (1990), are inconsistent with evidence that CF news dominates
over returns. The main reason anomaly portfolios’ returns are volatile is that
CF shocks are highly correlated across firms with similar characteristics. For
example, the long-short investment portfolio is volatile mainly because the CFs
of a typical high-investment firm are more strongly correlated with the CFs of
other high-investment firms than with those of low-investment firms. The small
variance of anomaly DR news does not imply small variation in the conditional
expected returns to anomaly portfolios. Indeed, we find substantial variation
in anomalies’ one-year expected returns, consistent with, for example, Haddad,
Kozak, and Santosh (2018). However, because this expected return variation is
not highly persistent, it has a small impact on stock prices and thus realized
anomaly returns.
Second, theories that emphasize commonality in DRs, such as theories of
time-varying risk aversion (e.g., Santos and Veronesi (2010)) and theories of
common investor sentiment (Baker and Wurgler (2006)), are difficult to recon-
cile with the low correlations between anomaly and market DR shocks. Third,
theories in which anomaly CF news is strongly correlated with market CF
news, in particular CF beta stories such as Zhang (2005), are inconsistent with
3At the firm level, our results with and without microcaps are consistent with the finding in
V02 that the correlation between CFs and DRs is highest for the smallest firms as well as with
the finding in Mendenhall (2004) that postearnings announcement drift is concentrated in the
smallest firms.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT