Vertical Integration and Exclusive Behavior of Insurers and Hospitals

Date01 June 2014
AuthorRein Halbersma,Katalin Katona,Rudy Douven,Victoria Shestalova
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12056
Published date01 June 2014
Vertical Integration and Exclusive Behavior
of Insurers and Hospitals
RUDY DOUVEN
CPB, Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis
P.O.Box 80510, 2508 GM, The Hague, the Netherlands and iBMG, Erasmus University Rotterdam,
the Netherlands
r.douven@cpb.nl
REIN HALBERSMA
Dutch Healthcare Authority
P.O.Box 3017, 3502 GA Utrecht, the Netherlands and TILEC, Tilburg University, the Netherlands
rhalbersma@nza.nl
KATALIN KATONA
Dutch Healthcare Authority
P.O.Box 3017, 3502 GA Utrecht, the Netherlands and TILEC, Tilburg University, the Netherlands
kkatona@nza.nl
VICTORIA SHESTALOVA
CPB, Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis
P.O.Box 80510, 2508 GM, The Hague, the Netherlands
v.shestalova@cpb.nl
We examine vertical integration and exclusive behavior in health care markets in which insurers
and hospitals bilaterally bargain over contracts. We employ a bargaining model of two hospitals
and two health insurers competing on premiums. We show that asymmetric equilibria exist in
which one insurer contracts one hospital whereas the other insurer contracts both hospitals, even
if all players are equally efficient in their production. Asymmetric equilibria arise if hospitals are
sufficiently differentiated. In these cases, total industry profits increase and consumer welfare
decreases in comparison to the case in which both insurers have contracts with both hospitals.
Vertical integration makes these equilibria possible for a wider range of parameters.
1. Introduction
One of the main challenges in health care is to reduce costs by providing health care
more efficiently. A market-oriented approach has been followed in the United States
and also recently in Europe, an approach in which competing health insurers and health
care providers should in theory achieve an efficient allocation of the production and
consumption of health care. This approach may stimulate the appearance of new forms
Wewould like to thank Paul de Bijl, Jan Boone, Marcel Canoy,Martin Gaynor, Katherine Ho, Viktoria Kocsis,
Erik Schut, Misja Mikkers for their comments on preliminary versions of our paper. Furthermore, we thank
participants of the IHEA conference in Beijing (2009) and EARIE conference in Ljubljana (2009), and our
colleagues at the CPB and NZA for their comments during seminars at our institutes. Martin Gaynor and
Katherine Ho were commissioned by the Dutch Healthcare Authority as external reviewers of an earlier
draft of this paper. We are grateful to two anonymous referees and the coeditor for their careful and detailed
comments and suggestions.
C2014 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume23, Number 2, Summer 2014, 344–368
Vertical Relations between Insurers and Hospitals 345
of institutional and contractual arrangements in the health-care sector. For example, the
growth of managed-care in the United States has led to tighter vertical relationships
between health insurers and providers in the form of health maintenance organizations
(HMO). In these organizations insurers’ enrollees typically receive full reimbursement
for services from providers within the network, whereas sometimes facing copayments
when visiting providers outside the network. Vertical restraints or integration can be a
tool for insurers and providers to gain efficiency, but they may also have anticompetitive
effects. The potential consequences of vertical integration between an insurer and a
hospital are currently cause for concern in Europe. For instance, the question of these
consequences has been discussed by the Dutch Parliament, and the current government
in the Netherlands now plans a per se prohibition of vertical integration between an
insurer and a hospital.1
In this paper, we examine under which market conditions exclusive behavior and
vertical integration can arise and whether this may harm competition. We study this
question with a bilateral-duopoly model of a competitive health care market, a model
in which insurers and hospitals bilaterally bargain over contracts.2We show that two
types of exclusive behavior can occur in this setting. First, one of the insurers may be
excluded. This happens if decreasing competition (i.e., monopolization) in the insurer
market leads to a substantial increase in total industry profits. Second, one hospital
may not, in equilibrium, engage in a contract with one of the insurers. In such a case, a
managed-care insurer (contracting one hospital) and a conventional insurer (contracting
both hospitals) can coexist in the market, even if both insurers and both hospitals are
equally efficient in their production. Weshow that the range of parameters under which
the latter outcome can occur grows if one insurer–hospital pair integrates vertically. The
modeled result that both managed-care and conventional health plans can coexist in the
market is new, because earlier literature on this topic (Gal-Or, 1997; Ma, 1997) focused
on exclusionary outcomes. Our model draws from Gal-Or (1997) but incorporates the
bargaining concept developed by de Fontenay and Gans (2005). The key difference with
Gal-Or (1997) is that both hospitals and insurers are modeled as strategic players; they
bargain over profit allocation, rather than over linear contracts.
The paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2, we describe the literature and our
contribution to it. We develop our model in Section 3, which we use in Section 4 to
characterize equilibrium outcomes in the cases with and without vertical integration of
a hospital and an insurer.Section 5 provides the analysis of consumer welfare. In the last
section, we draw conclusions and outline directions for further research. We relegate to
the appendix more technical details concerning the bargaining approach used.
2. Literature and Contribution
Managed-care organizations use various forms of vertical arrangement to reduce the
cost of providing health care and to improve the quality of care. There is evidence that
a vertically integrated network may enhance consumer welfare by providing health
care more efficiently. Many studies on the United States have shown that insurance
provided by managed-care organizations cost 10–20% less than indemnity insurance.
1. Source: The coalition agreement of the Dutch government of September 30, 2010 (http://www.
rijksoverheid.nl/regering/het-kabinet/regeerakkoord).
2. Inthe remainder of the paper we will use the term hospitals, because we primarily focus on this subject,
but a more general term, such as health care providers, would be applicable as well.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT