Venture Capital and Capital Allocation

Published date01 June 2019
Date01 June 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12756
AuthorGIORGIA PIACENTINO
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXIV, NO. 3 JUNE 2019
Venture Capital and Capital Allocation
GIORGIA PIACENTINO
ABSTRACT
I show that venture capitalists’ motivation to build reputation can have beneficial
effects in the primary market, mitigating information frictions and helping firms go
public. Because uninformed reputation-motivated venture capitalists want to appear
informed, they are biased against backing firms—by not backing firms, they avoid
taking low-value firms to market, which would ultimately reveal their lack of infor-
mation. In equilibrium, reputation-motivated venture capitalists back relatively few
bad firms, creating a certification effect that mitigates information frictions. However,
they also back relatively few good firms, and thus, reputation motivation decreases
welfare when good firms are abundant or profitable.
DELEGATED INVESTORS WISH TO BE perceived as skilled in order to generate
“flows,” that is, to attract new investors and retain existing ones. This motiva-
tion to build a reputation for being skilled can distort their trades in secondary
markets. For example, delegated investors may trade too much in an attempt
to appear informed, even when they are not. Such excessive portfolio churning
can decrease secondary market efficiency (Dow and Gorton (1997), Dasgupta
and Prat (2006,2008), Guerrieri and Kondor (2012)). However, delegated in-
vestors play an important role not only in secondary markets, where their
trading behavior affects market efficiency, but also in primary markets, where
their investment behavior affects real efficiency. In particular, venture capital
firms (VCs) decide which firms to back and thus which projects go ahead. In this
paper, I ask whether VCs’ reputation motivation leads to inefficiencies in pri-
mary markets. Specifically, I examine whether reputation motivation induces
VCs to back the wrong firms in an attempt to appear skilled.
Giorgia Piacentino is with Columbia University and CEPR. I thank three anonymous referees,
the Associate Editor,and the Editor, Bruno Biais. I am also grateful to Ulf Axelson; the late Sudipto
Bhattacharya; Sugato Bhattacharya; Philip Bond; Mike Burkart; Amil Dasgupta; James Dow; Ja-
son Roderick Donaldson; Alex Edmans; Daniel Ferreira; Itay Goldstein; Radhakrishnan Gopalan;
Denis Gromb; Christian Julliard; Ohad Kadan; Peter Kondor; Todd Milbourn; Daniel Paravisini;
Christopher Polk; Uday Rajan; Anjan Thakor; David Thesmar; Dimitri Vayanos; Michela Verardo;
Kathy Yuan; Konstantinos Zachariadis; Hongda Zhong; and audiences at Amsterdam Business
School, Arizona State University, Bocconi University, the 2013 EFA meeting, EIEF, Federal Re-
serve Board of Governors, the 2013 FIRS conference, HEC Paris, the 2017 Institutional Investors
and Corporate Governance conference at the Swedish House of Finance, UBC, UNC, University
of Maryland, University of Michigan, Stockholm School of Economics, University of Pennsylva-
nia, University of Warwick, and Washington University in St. Louis. I have read the Journal of
Finance’s disclosure policy and have no conflict of interest to disclose.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12756
1261
1262 The Journal of Finance R
To address these questions, I develop a model in which a VC may be
reputation-motivated, instead of purely profit motivated. Surprisingly, I find
that, in equilibrium, the VC’s profits can be higher than they would be if it
were just trying to maximize them. The reason is that reputation motivation
changes a VC’s behavior, leading it to reduce the number of firms it backs,
and this creates a certification effect that mitigates information frictions at the
time of IPO. Reputation motivation is not all good, however, as it can also lead
a VC not to back some relatively good firms. Thus, reputation motivation leads
a VC to back not only fewer bad firms, but also fewer good firms. The net effect
on total welfare and VC profits therefore depends on the proportion and quality
of good firms in the market.
Model Preview. A penniless start-up firm requires outside finance for an
investment that may be good or bad. It looks for a VC to back it, that is, to
provide capital and expertise. If the firm receives backing, it gives the VC an
equity stake and invests. Later, the firm raises capital from uninformed bidders
in an initial public offering (IPO), in which the VC retains its stake in the firm.
Finally, the long-run value of the investment is realized.
The VC can be skilled or unskilled. If it is skilled, it can observe whether the
firm (i.e., its investment) is good or bad; if it is unskilled, it observes nothing.
I consider two cases. First, the VC may be profit-motivated, that is, it wants
to back the firm whenever it expects to make a profit for its current investors.
Second, the VC may be reputation-motivated, that is, it wants to maximize the
market’s belief that it is skilled, so as to maximize the capital it can raise from
future investors.
Results Preview. I first characterize the equilibrium with a profit-motivated
VC. A skilled VC knows the quality of the firm. As a result, it does not back bad
firms, while it backs good firms as long as it anticipates being able to take them
to IPO. Hence, a skilled VC “filters out” bad firms. In contrast, an unskilled VC
does not know whether the firm is good or bad but it knows that the market
believes that VC-backed firms are better than average, due to the skilled VC’s
filtering. Thus, if the unskilled VC backs the firm, it raises cheap capital at the
time of the IPO, that is, it is subsidized by pooling with the positively informed
skilled VC. As a result, the unskilled VC may also back the firm, despite its lack
of information, as doing so maximizes its expected profits. However, this may
be socially inefficient. Indeed, the unskilled VC overinvests, that is, it may still
back a firm with negative net present value (NPV). When the average NPV is
low enough, the unskilled VC’s overinvestment can reduce the average quality
of VC-backed firms so much that IPO bidders are unwilling to provide capital.
Thus, in anticipation of being unable to IPO, skilled VCs do not back firms even
when they know they are good, that is, the collapse of the IPO market causes
the VC market to break down.
What changes if the VC is reputation-motivated? In this case, an unskilled
VC is averse to backing a firm that might end up being bad, but less averse
to not backing a firm that might end up being good. Since the firm’s value
is revealed only if the VC backs it, the market can determine whether the VC
wrongly backed a bad firm but not whether the VC wrongly rejected a good firm.
Venture Capital and Capital Allocation 1263
Put differently, the market can distinguish between false positives and true
positives, but cannot distinguish between false negatives and true negatives.
This biases the unskilled VC toward “negatives,” that is, toward not backing
the firm, which makes the unskilled reputation-motivated VC conservative—it
backs firms less frequently than an unskilled profit-motivated VC.
When the unskilled reputation-motivated VC rejects a firm, it is doing some-
thing that decreases its profits—if it just maximized its profits, it would act
like the unskilled profit-motivated VC and overinvest to get the IPO subsidy
from the skilled VC. However, even though it is not trying to maximize them,
these profits can still be higher than those of the unskilled profit-motivated
VC in equilibrium. The reason is that its conservatism leads to a certification
effect that can increase efficiency in two ways. First, it can prevent market
breakdowns: since unskilled reputation-motivated VCs back firms relatively
rarely, many VC-backed firms are backed by positively informed skilled VCs.
The market therefore infers that VC-backed firms are probably good. This effect
mitigates information frictions and helps firms go public. Second, even absent
market breakdowns, a VC’s conservatism can increase aggregate efficiency.
Relative to the profit-motivated VC, the reputation-motivated VC backs fewer
good firms, but also fewer bad firms. The net effect of this behavior for social
efficiency depends on firms’ average NPV. If it is negative, aggregate efficiency
is higher with reputation-motivated VCs, as they back firms less often than
profit-motivated VCs. In contrast, if firms’ average NPV is positive, aggregate
efficiency is lower with reputation-motivated VCs, as in this case, the costs of
backing fewer good firms outweigh the benefits of backing fewer bad firms.
Below, I place a bit more emphasis on the negative-NPV case, and hence on
the positive effects of reputation motivation because I think this case may be
more important in practice. VC partners “source a few thousand opportunities,
invest in a handful, and get returns from a few”; indeed, “almost 80 percent of
all investments fail” (Ramsinghani (2014, p. 69 and p. 6)). That said, although
the total population of firms that VCs could possibly back may have negative
average NPV, the set of firms in my model could represent a subset of this pop-
ulation, with the worst already partially filtered out. Under this interpretation,
the positive average NPV case becomes important too.
Extensions and Robustness. I show that the positive side of reputation mo-
tivation is robust to a number of extensions, two of which are particularly
important. First, I include adverse selection among IPO bidders, so that the
firm must issue shares at a discount to induce uninformed bidders to par-
ticipate. I show that the results are robust to this more realistic model of
an IPO. More importantly, I show that VCs’ reputation motivation can im-
prove welfare even if the average NPV is positive. Indeed, by not backing firms
with low but positive NPV—something that would typically be inefficient—the
certification effect of reputation-motivated VCs is strong enough to overcome
adverse-selection-induced market breakdowns.
Second, I allow the unskilled VC to be partially informed. In particular,
I assume that it gets a continuous signal about the quality of the firm, so
it backs firms only if its signal is above a threshold. As in the baseline, an

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT