Valuing Stakeholder Governance: Property Rights, Community Mobilization, and Firm Value

Date01 December 2017
AuthorKate Odziemkowska,Sinziana Dorobantu
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2675
Published date01 December 2017
Strategic Management Journal
Strat. Mgmt. J.,38: 2682–2703 (2017)
Published online EarlyView 31 July 2017 in WileyOnline Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com) DOI: 10.1002/smj.2675
Received 9 March 2016;Final revisionreceived 10 May 2017
Valuing Stakeholder Governance: Property Rights,
Community Mobilization, and Firm Value
Sinziana Dorobantu1*and Kate Odziemkowska2
1Department of Management and Organizations, Stern School of Business, New
York University, New York, New York
2Management Department, The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania,
Philadelphia, Pennsylvania
Research summary: While researchhas shown that good stakeholder relations increase the value
of a rm, less is known about how specic types of stakeholder governance affect rm value. We
examine the value of one such governance mechanism—community benets agreements (CBAs)
signed by rms and local communities— intended to minimize social conict that disrupts access
to valuable resources. We argue that shareholders evaluate more positively CBAs with local
communities with strongproperty rights and histories of institutional action and extra-institutional
mobilization because these communities are more likelyto cause costly disruptions and delays for
a rm. We evaluate these arguments by analyzing the cumulative abnormal returns associated
with the unexpected announcement of 148 CBAs signed between mining companies and local
indigenous communities in Canada.
Managerial summary: With rms across many industries facing escalating costs associated with
social conict, new tools are emergingto help rms mitigate these risks by seeking the support of
the local communities in which they operate.Community benets agreements (CBAs) are contracts
in which a community provides consent for a new investment in return for tangible benets, such
as local hiring and revenue sharing. We argue that although CBAs arecostly for the rm, they are
particularly valuable when communities can cause costly disruptions and delays for a rm. Our
study of investor reactions to the announcement of 148 CBAs signed between mining companies
and local indigenous communities in Canada shows that investors value more CBAs signed with
communities with strong property rights and histories of protest. Copyright © 2017 John Wiley
& Sons, Ltd.
Large-scale projects can profoundly transform local
communities, economies, and environments, and
they often lead to social conict between compa-
nies and local communities. In a recent example,
American Indians of the Standing Rock Sioux tribe,
Keywords: stakeholder governance;property rights; social
movements; local communities; corporate social responsi-
bility
*Correspondence to: Sinziana Dorobantu, Department of Man-
agement and Organizations, Stern School of Business, New York
University, 40 West 4th Street, Suite 707, New York, NY 10012.
E-mail: sdoroban@stern.nyu.edu
[Correction made on 9/28/2017, after rst online publication:
The Dakota Access oil pipeline was originally notes as being
1,183 Km. It is actually 1,900 Km. We apologize for the error.]
Copyright © 2017 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
whose reservation borders the charted path of the
$3.7 billion, 1,900 Km Dakota Access oil pipeline,
have been protesting against the construction of
the pipeline, claiming that it traverses ancestral
lands and that oil spills would be ruinous to their
well-being. In August 2016, they asked a federal
court in Washington, DC, to issue an injunction
that would halt the pipeline’s construction (Healy,
2016). Although the court denied the request, the
U.S. government ordered a pause in the construc-
tion, raising concerns over the pipeline’s future
(Healy & Schwartz, 2016). As this example illus-
trates, social conict is associated with signicant
disruptions and delays that increase operational
Valuing Stakeholder Governance 2683
costs (Franks et al., 2014), lower the market val-
uation of planned or existing operations (Henisz,
Dorobantu, & Nartey, 2014), and potentially delay
entry into new markets (Ingram, Yue, & Rao, 2010).
In a number of industries (including mining, oil
and gas, renewable energy, agriculture, forestry,real
estate, and infrastructure), rms are increasingly
relying on legally enforceable contracts known as
community benets agreements (CBAs)1to govern
their relationships with local communities. These
agreements enable rms and local communities to
converge on a mutually acceptable distribution of
value, ensuring that local communities receivecom-
pensation for the resources they provide and for
the social and environmental disruptions associ-
ated with these projects. Existing CBAs cover large
real estate developments, such as Pacic Park (for-
merly known as Atlantic Yards) in Brooklyn, New
York, and have become an established feature of
onshore wind developments in the United Kingdom
(Cowell, Bristow, & Munday, 2011). In the min-
ing sector in Canada— the empirical context of our
study— there are over 350 publicly disclosed CBAs
with indigenous communities (Natural Resources
Canada, 2014).
In all these industries, access to specic
resources— a well-located site or a land area rich
in natural resources— requires the consent of
the local community; without it, the rm’s local
operations may be disrupted or delayed, leading
to costly adjustments. Because local communities
are sovereign entities, the exchange relationship
through which communities grant a rm access to
site-specic resources cannot be internalized within
the hierarchical structure of the rm, as predicted
by transaction costs economics (Williamson, 1985).
Firms cannot merge with or acquire local commu-
nities. Similarly, access to specic resources may
not be ensured through relational contracts (Baker,
Gibbons, & Murphy, 2002; Gibbons & Henderson,
2012; Macaulay, 1963) where communities have
strong incentives to extract more value from a
project once it is underway. As a result, contractual
agreements become a mechanism for governing
the relationship between a rm and the local com-
munity whose cooperation is critical for the rm’s
1We use the term community benets agreements (Cain, 2014;
Parks & Warren, 2009; Salkin & Lavine, 2008) to also include
agreements referred to as community development agreements
(O’Faircheallaigh, 2015b) and impact and benet agreements
(Sosa & Keenan, 2001).
access to valuable resources, and consequently, for
its nancial performance.2
In this article, we examine whether rms can cre-
ate value through CBAs. By legally binding both
parties to pre-agreed terms, CBAs reduce the likeli-
hood of conict with the local community,lowering
the probability of disruptions and delays associated
with such conicts, and therefore, increasing the
ability of managers to stay on schedule and within
budget. But such agreements are costly to negoti-
ate and implement: They commit the rm to shar-
ing part of the value created with the community;
they require specialized negotiators and managerial
time; and they can delay regulatory approvals and
operations schedules. Thus, given that CBAs entail
not only benets, but also signicant costs, investors
may not always perceive them as adding value to
the rm. Instead, they may view CBAs as diverting
resources from shareholder value maximization to
short-term conict avoidance (Friedman, 1962), or
as symbolic acts of impression management (Els-
bach, Sutton, & Principe, 1998) with limited impli-
cations for value creation.
We argue that CBAs add value to a rm when
they are signed with communities who can obstruct
a rm’s access to valuable resources through their
strong property rights or their ability to mobilize
against the rm using social movement tactics (such
as protests or blockades) or institutional tactics
(such as legal action or interference in the regulatory
process). Such communities are more likely to enter
into conict with the rm, leading to disruptions
and delays that negatively impact its value. As
CBAs are a means of lowering the probability of
such disruptions, they are likely to be perceived by
investors as valueenhancing, but only when they are
signed with communities that pose a considerable
risk of disrupting rm operations.
We assess the nancial value of CBAs by
analyzing market reactions to the unexpected
announcement of 148 agreements between local
indigenous communities and 95 rms in the Cana-
dian mining industry. CBAs are negotiated in strict
condentiality, and the most pertinent information
disclosed during their announcement is the signing
2We do not mean to suggest here that contractual agreements
and relational governance are mutually exclusive, but only that
a contractual agreement is necessary when the rm is highly
dependent on the consent of the local community. In fact, much
of the argument we develop below rests on the idea that the
negotiation of a CBA lays the foundation for a relational contract
that is likely to complement the formal contractual agreement.
Copyright © 2017 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,38: 2682–2703 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/smj

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT