Valuation Risk and Asset Pricing

Published date01 December 2016
AuthorVICTOR XI LUO,SERGIO REBELO,RUI ALBUQUERQUE,MARTIN EICHENBAUM
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12437
Date01 December 2016
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXI, NO. 6 DECEMBER 2016
Valuation Risk and Asset Pricing
RUI ALBUQUERQUE, MARTIN EICHENBAUM, VICTOR XI LUO,
and SERGIO REBELO
ABSTRACT
Standard representative-agent models fail to account for the weak correlation be-
tween stock returns and measurable fundamentals, such as consumption and output
growth. This failing, which underlies virtually all modern asset pricing puzzles, arises
because these models load all uncertainty onto the supply side of the economy. We
propose a simple theory of asset pricing in which demand shocks play a central role.
These shocks give rise to valuation risk that allows the model to account for key asset
pricing moments, such as the equity premium, the bond term premium, and the weak
correlation between stock returns and fundamentals.
IN STANDARD REPRESENTATIVE-AGENT ASSET pricing models, the expected return
to an asset reflects the covariance between the asset’s payoff and the agent’s
stochastic discount factor (SDF). An important challenge to these models is
that the correlation and covariance between stock returns and measurable
fundamentals, especially consumption growth, is weak at both short and long
horizons. Cochrane and Hansen (1992), Campbell and Cochrane (1999), and
Cochrane (2001) call this phenomenon the correlation puzzle. More recently,
Lettau and Ludvigson (2011) document this puzzle using different methods.
According to their estimates, the shock that accounts for the vast majority
of asset price fluctuations is uncorrelated with consumption at virtually all
horizons.
The basic disconnect between measurable macroeconomic fundamentals and
stock returns underlies virtually all modern asset pricing puzzles, including
Albuquerque is with Boston College, CEPR, and ECGI; Eichenbaum is with Northwestern Uni-
versity, NBER, and the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago; Luo is with Northwestern University;
and Rebelo is with Northwestern University, NBER, and CEPR. We benefited from the comments
and suggestions of Fernando Alvarez, Ravi Bansal, Frederico Belo, Jaroslav Borovicka, John Camp-
bell, John Cochrane, Lars Hansen, Anisha Ghosh, Ravi Jaganathan, Tasos Karantounias, Howard
Kung, Junghoon Lee, Dmitry Livdan, Jonathan Parker, Alberto Rossi, Costis Skiadas, Ivan Wern-
ing, and Amir Yaron. We thank Robert Barro, Emi Nakamura, Jun Steinsson, and Jose Ursua
for sharing their data with us and Benjamin Johannsen for superb research assistance. Albu-
querque gratefully acknowledges financial support from the European Union Seventh Framework
Programme (FP7/2007-2013) under grant agreement PCOFUND-GA-2009-246542 and from the
Foundation for Science and Technology-FCT under grant PTDC/IIM-FIN/2977/2014. A previous
version of this paper was presented under the title “Understanding the Equity Premium Puzzle
and the Correlation Puzzle,” http://tinyurl.com/akfmvxb. The authors have read the Journal of
Finance’s disclosure policy and have no conflicts of interest to disclose.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12437
2861
2862 The Journal of Finance R
the equity premium puzzle, Hansen and Singleton (1982)-style rejection of
asset pricing models, violation of Hansen and Jagannathan (1991) bounds, and
Shiller (1981)-style observations about excess stock price volatility.
A central finding of modern empirical finance is that variation in asset re-
turns is overwhelmingly due to variation in discount factors (see Campbell and
Ammer (1993) and Cochrane (2011)). A key question is: how should we model
this variation? In classic asset pricing models, all uncertainty is loaded onto
the supply side of the economy.In Lucas (1978) tree models, agents are exposed
to random endowment shocks, while in production economies they are exposed
to random productivity shocks. Both classes of models abstract from shocks to
the demand for assets. Not surprisingly, it is very difficult for these models to
simultaneously resolve the equity premium puzzle and the correlation puzzle.
We propose a simple theory of asset pricing in which demand shocks, arising
from stochastic changes in agents’ rate of time preference, play a central role in
the determination of asset prices. These shocks amount to a parsimonious way
of modeling the variation in discount rates stressed by Campbell and Ammer
(1993) and Cochrane (2011). Our model implies that the law of motion for
these shocks plays a first-order role in determining the equilibrium behavior
of variables like the price-dividend ratio, equity returns, and bond yields. Our
analysis is disciplined by the fact that the law of motion for time preference
shocks must be consistent with the time-series properties of these variables.
In our model, the representative agent has recursive preferences of the type
considered by Kreps and Porteus (1978), Weil (1989), and Epstein and Zin
(1991). When the risk aversion coefficient is equal to the inverse of the elasticity
of intertemporal substitution, recursive preferences reduce to constant relative
risk aversion (CRRA) preferences. We show that, in this case, time preference
shocks have negligible effects on key asset pricing moments such as the equity
premium.
We consider two versions of our model. The benchmark model is designed to
highlight the role played by time preference shocks per se. Here consumption
and dividends are modeled as random walks with conditionally homoskedas-
tic shocks. However, while this model is useful for expositional purposes, it
suffers from clear empirical shortcomings, for example, the equity premium is
constant. We thus consider an extended version of the model in which shocks
to the consumption and dividend process are conditionally heteroskedastic. We
find that adding these features improves the performance of the model.1
We estimate our model using a Simulated Method of Moments (SMM) strat-
egy implemented with annual data for the period 1929 to 2011. We assume that
agents make decisions on a monthly basis. We then deduce the model’s implica-
tions for annual data, that is, we explicitly deal with the temporal aggregation
problem.2
1These results parallel the findings of Bansal and Yaron (2004), who show that allowing for
conditional heteroskedasticity improves the performance of long-run risk models.
2Bansal, Kiku, and Yaron(2013) pursue a similar strategy in estimating a long-run risk model.
They estimate the frequency with which agents make decisions and find that it is roughly equal to
one month.
Valuation Risk and Asset Pricing 2863
It turns out that, for a large set of parameter values, our model implies
that the SMM estimators suffer from substantial small-sample bias. This bias
is particularly large for moments characterizing the predictability of excess
returns and the decomposition of the variance of the price-dividend ratio pro-
posed by Cochrane (1992). In light of this fact, we modify the SMM procedure to
focus on the plim of the model-implied small-sample moments rather than the
plim of the moments themselves. This change makes an important difference
in assessing the model’s empirical performance.
We show that time preference shocks help explain the equity premium as long
as the risk aversion coefficient and the elasticity of intertemporal substitution
are both greater than one or both smaller than one. This condition is satisfied
in the estimated benchmark and extended models.
Allowing for sampling uncertainty, our model accounts for the equity pre-
mium and the volatility of stock and bond returns, even though the estimated
degree of agents’ risk aversion is moderate (roughly 1.5). Critically, the ex-
tended model also accounts for the mean, variance, and persistence of the
price-dividend ratio and the risk-free rate. In addition, it accounts for the cor-
relation between stock returns and fundamentals such as consumption, output,
and dividend growth at short, medium, and long horizons. The model also ac-
counts for the observed predictability of excess returns by lagged price-dividend
ratios.
We define valuation risk as the part of the excess return to an asset that is
due to the volatility of the time preference shock. According to our estimates,
valuation risk is a much more important determinant of asset returns than
conventional risk. Valuation risk is an increasing function of an asset’s matu-
rity, so a natural test of our model is whether it can account for the bond term
premia. We show that the model does a good job at accounting for the level and
slope of the nominal yield curve, as well as the standard deviation of nominal
yields. The upward-sloping nature of the nominal yield curve reflects the fact
that our model predicts an upward-sloping yield curve for ex ante real yields
on nominal bonds. In fact, in our model the slope of the yield curve is driven
entirely by valuation risk.
The last result contrasts sharply with leading alternatives such as the long-
run risk model, which generally predicts a downward-sloping real yield curve.
With this distinction in mind, we discuss evidence on the slope of the real yield
curve obtained using data for the United States and the United Kingdom. We
also show that the estimated nominal SDF for our model has the properties
that Backus and Zin (1994) argue are necessary to simultaneously account for
the slope of the yield curve and the persistence of bond yields.
An extant literature models shocks to the demand for assets as arising from
time preference or taste shocks. For example, Garber and King (1983)and
Campbell (1986) consider these types of shocks in early work on asset pric-
ing. Stockman and Tesar (1995), Pavlova and Rigobon (2007), and Gabaix and
Maggiori (2013) study the role of taste shocks in explaining asset prices in
open-economy models. In the macroeconomic literature, Eggertsson and Wood-
ford (2003) and Eggertsson (2004) model changes in savings behavior as arising

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT