Upstream Mergers, Downstream Competition, and R&D Investments

Published date01 December 2013
AuthorApostolis Pavlou,Chrysovalantou Milliou
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12034
Date01 December 2013
Upstream Mergers, Downstream Competition, and
R&D Investments
CHRYSOVALANTOU MILLIOU
Department of International and European Economic Studies
Athens University of Economics and Business
Athens 10434, Greece
cmilliou@aueb.gr
APOSTOLIS PAVLOU
Department of Economics
Athens University of Economics and Business
Athens 10434, Greece
pavlou@aueb.gr
In this paper, we provide an explanation for why upstream firms merge, highlighting the role of
R&D investments and their nature, as well as the role of downstream competition. We show that
an upstream merger generates two distinct efficiency gains when downstream competition is not
too strong and R&D investments are sufficiently generic: The merger increasesR&D investments
and decreases wholesale prices. We also show that upstreamfirms merge unless R&D investments
are too specific and downstream competition is neither too weak nor too strong. When the merger
materializes, the merger-generated efficiencies pass on to consumers, and thus, consumers can be
better off.
1. Introduction
Mergers among manufacturers of either intermediate or final products are a very com-
mon business phenomenon. They can be found in various industry sectors. For instance,
car equipment suppliers merge with each other (Kolben-schmidt/Pierburg), and so do
producers of chemical substances (BASF/Engelhard), as well as mobile phone manu-
facturers (Sony/Ericsson).1
A quite common characteristic of mergers among manufacturers is that the merged
firms do not sell their products directly to consumers. Usually, they sell their products to
other firms, final product manufacturers, or retailers, which then provide the products
We thank Stephane Caprice, George Deltas, Emmanuel Petrakis, Patrick Rey, Nikolaos Vettas, the co-editor,
and two anonymous referees for their useful comments and suggestions. Wealso thank seminar participants
at the Toulouse School of Economics, the Athens University of Economics and Business, and the CERGE-EI
(Prague), as well as conference participants at the 7th International Industrial Organization Conference at
Boston, the 8th Conference on Research on Economic Theory and Econometrics at Tinos,and the ASSET 2009
conferenceat Istanbul. This is a substantially revised version of the previously circulated “Upstream Horizontal
Mergersand Efficiency Gains,” CESifo Working Paper 2748. This research has been cofinanced by the European
Union (European Social Fund—ESF) and Greek national funds through the Operational Program “Education
and Lifelong Learning” of the National Strategic Reference Framework (NSRF)—Research Funding Program:
Heracleitus II—Investing in knowledge society through the European Social Fund. Full responsibility for all
shortcomings is ours.
1. Moreover,there have been proposed mergers among baby food manufacturers (Heinz/Beech-Nut) and
among cigar producers (Swedish Match/Scandinavian Tobacco). For additional examples see Froeb et al.
(2007).
C2013 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume22, Number 4, Winter 2013, 787–809
788 Journal of Economics & Management Strategy
to consumers. In other words, typically mergers among manufacturers involve firms
that operate in the upstream sectors of vertically related industries.
One of the recent concerns of the antitrust authorities in the treatment of mergers
between manufacturers is whether they should take vertical relationships into account
(see e.g., Scheffman and Coleman, 2002; Froeb et al., 2004,2007). That is, whether they
should consider the downstream behavior when they examine upstream merger pro-
posals. Such a concern is mainly motivated by the recent increase in retail concentration,
which implies that the assumption of many studies examining manufacturer mergers
that retailers are passive is quite unrealistic.
In this paper, we study upstream mergers in vertically related industries. A key
aspect of our analysis is that we allow for R&D investments and we consider the role
of their nature, whether they are specific or generic. Two additional key aspects of our
analysis are that we endogenize the contract types used in vertical trading and we
take into account downstream competition and its intensity. We address a number of
questions such as: Why and when upstream firms merge? Do upstream mergers lead to
efficiency gains? How do they influence vertical trading? Are their potential efficiency
gains passed on to consumers? Do upstream mergers harm welfare?
In our model, there are initially two upstream and two downstream firms with
exclusive relations among them. In the outset, the upstream firms decide whether they
will merge. Next, they choose among trading through wholesale price contracts or
two-part tariff contracts, they invest in R&D and they set the contract terms.2Finally,
the downstream firms compete in quantities. We allow for various degrees of R&D
investments’ specificity. If the R&D investments are fully specific, they can be used in
the production of the input of just one downstream firm. Otherwise, they can be used
in the production of the inputs of both downstream firms.
We find that a merger can alter the equilibrium contract types. Premerger, firms
trade always through two-part tariff contracts. Two-part tariff contracts, in contrast to
wholesale price contracts, do not result into double marginalization and they maximize
the vertical chain’s profits. Postmerger, firms trade through two-part tariffs only when
products are not too close substitutes. Otherwise, they trade through both contract types.
Under trading through two-part tariffs, the upstream firm(s) subsidize the downstream
production. Premerger, subsidization occurs because each upstream firm wishes to make
its downstream customer more aggressive. Postmerger, subsidization is due to the up-
stream monopolist’s “commitment problem.” As products get closer, substitutes and
downstream competition increases, the “commitment problem” gets more severe, and
the merged firm switches to trading through both contract types.
We also find that an upstream merger can have two distinct efficiency gains: It
increases the R&D investments, and thus, the upstream cost-efficiency, and decreases
the wholesale prices. This occurs as long as downstream competition is not too strongand
R&D investments are not too specific. The merger’s positive impact on R&D investments
is mainly driven by the fact that when R&D investments are not too specific, they reduce
2. These two contracts types are commonly used in the vertical relations literature and they are also
commonly used by firms (for empirical evidence see e.g., Smith and Thanassoulis, 2009, and Bonnet and
Dubois, 2010). To the best of our knowledge, Gal-Or (1991), Rey and Stiglitz (1995), Milliou and Petrakis
(2007), and Milliou et al. (2009) are the only papers that endogenize the contract types. These papers, with
the exception of Milliou et al. (2009), restrict the contract types choice to that among these two contract types.
Milliou et al. (2009), in a setting without upstream mergersand R &D investments, consider also price–quantity
bundle contracts, which specify the total input quantity and its total price. In Section 6,webrieydiscuss
what happens under such contracts.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT