Unshrouding: Evidence from Bank Overdrafts in Turkey

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12593
Published date01 April 2018
Date01 April 2018
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXIII, NO. 2 APRIL 2018
Unshrouding: Evidence from Bank Overdrafts
in Turkey
SULE ALAN, MEHMET CEMALCILAR, DEAN KARLAN,
and JONATHAN ZINMAN
ABSTRACT
Lower prices produce higher demand . . . or do they? A bank’s direct marketing to
holders of “free” checking accounts shows that a large discount on 60% APR over-
drafts reduces overdraft usage, especially when bundled with a discount on debit card
or autodebit transactions. In contrast, messages mentioning overdraft availability
without mentioning price increase usage. Neither change persists long after the mes-
sages stop. These results do not square easily with classical models of consumer choice
and firm competition. Instead, they support behavioral models where consumers un-
derestimate and are inattentive to overdraft costs, and firms respond by shrouding
overdraft prices in equilibrium.
MANY BUSINESS MODELS IN FINANCIAL services and other industries rely on expen-
sive add-ons that are tied to base goods. Examples include expensive overdraft
credit (add-on) tied to a “free” checking account (base good), back-end man-
agement fees tied to “free” investment advice, printer cartridges and printers,
luggage fees and airline tickets, and dealer-supplied maintenance and auto-
mobiles. A closely related practice is overage/penalty pricing. Businesses with
such revenue models typically focus their marketing and competitive strategy
on the base good, even though add-ons/overages can be critical revenue sources.
Retail banking provides a striking example: banks often market checking
accounts as free, even though many consumers end up paying high fees for
overdraft credit.1Government audits find that banks rarely market overdraft
services at the customer acquisition stage and even actively discourage em-
ployees from providing information on overdraft terms (General Accounting
Sule Alan is at the University of Essex and Koc University. Mehmet Cemalcılar is at the Koc
University. Dean Karlan is at the Northwestern University, IPA, J-PAL, and NBER. Jonathan
Zinman is at Dartmouth College, IPA, J-PAL, and NBER. We thank Yapi Kredi staff for their
cooperation; Michael Grubb, Ben Keys, David Laibson, Eva Nagypal, Josh Schwartzstein, Andrei
Shleifer, and audiences at Boston College, Harvard/MIT, Kellogg (Finance), LSE, UCL, University
of Maryland, University of Virginia, the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, the CFPB Research
Conference, and the NBER Law & Economics group for comments; and Benni Savonitto, Glynis
Startz, and Zachary Groff for research management and analysis support. Authors did not have
direct conflicts of interest but are associated with other entities concerned with overdraft fees.
Disclosure information is available online.
1An overdraft occurs if the checking account holder initiates a transaction that makes her
balance negative or more negative.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12593
481
482 The Journal of Finance R
Office (2008), Competition and Markets Authority (2014), Consumer Financial
Protection Bureau v. TCF National Bank (2017)). After acquiring customers,
banks in some markets including Turkey, the site of our experiment, blur the
line between positive and negative balances by highlighting for customers
an available-to-withdraw figure that adds the available overdraft credit line
amount to the checking account balance, while making information on disag-
gregated balances and finance charges more difficult to find. Turkish banks
during our study period basically drew attention to overdrafts only when pro-
moting the feature to existing customers. Yet, even those promotions did not
explicitly mention the price of overdraft credit.
Why would a bank hide information on overdraft costs? After all, a classically
rational consumer would simply infer that shrouded prices are high prices. But
recent behavioral theories show that shrouded and high prices can persist if
consumers tend to underestimate their add-on costs and firms cannot profit
from debiasing consumers with more transparent pricing or information about
competitors’ high add-on prices (Gabaix and Laibson (2006), Grubb (2015),
Heidhues, K¨
oszegi, and Murooka (2017)).2
Bank regulators respond to such practices in various ways. For example,
in the United States regulators require upfront consumer opt-in for debit card
and ATM overdrafts, in both the United States and United Kingdom regulators
caution banks against relying too heavily on overdraft revenue, and in Turkey
regulators cap overdraft prices.
But empirical evidence is lacking on key questions raised by theory and
policy. Do consumers actually underestimate costs of add-ons such as over-
drafts?, do firms actually have incentives to shroud add-on prices instead of
competing to debias consumers?, how do consumers allocate attention to add-
ons?, and how quickly does consumer learning about add-ons break a shrouded
equilibrium? In short, empirical evidence on what drives overdraft pricing,
advertising, and usage is limited and largely descriptive.
These questions are central to overdraft markets. Beginning in the 1990s,
overdraft revenue replaced monthly subscription fees as banks’ major source
of explicit income from checking accounts, shifting the pricing equilibrium
for retail banking in much of the world to “free if nonnegative balance, very
expensive if in overdraft.” In the United States, banks collect more than
$10 billion in overdraft revenue annually.In the United Kingdom, banks derive
almost as much income from overdrafts as from reinvesting checking account
deposits (Competition and Markets Authority (2014)). In Turkey, the site of our
experiment, the announcement of a price ceiling on overdrafts was immedi-
ately followed by a 1.4% reduction in bank share prices, with a 2.1% drop for
the most overdraft-reliant bank (Toksabay (2013)).
We worked with Yapi Kredi (YK), one of the largest banks in Turkey, to de-
sign a randomized direct marketing experiment that distinguishes between
2For related evidence on consumer perceptions of overdraft costs, see Armstrong and Vick-
ers (2012) and Stango and Zinman (2014). For related models of limited and reactive consumer
attention, see, for example, Gabaix (2014) and Bordalo, Gennaioli, and Shleifer (2015).
Unshrouding: Evidence from Bank Overdrafts in Turkey 483
Figure 1. Experimental design. (Color figure can be viewed at wileyonlinelibrary.com)
classical and behavioral models of add-on pricing and advertising. YK sought
to learn more about its optimal strategy for pricing and advertising its over-
draft product. The bank was particularly interested in understanding whether
its past promotional pricing and advertising content tactics were effective in
increasing demand, and if not why not. YK’s interest rate (60% APR) and prod-
uct design was in line with standard practices and regulations. As is common
in overdraft markets, the product was priced expensively relative to seemingly
close substitutes (like credit cards), and disproportionally to credit risk (as
recently found by Turkish authorities).
YK sought to target marginal overdrafters among its existing client base, and
hence the experiment varied the promotions that YK sent via SMS (text mes-
sage) from September to December 2012 to 108,000 existing checking account
clients who had not overdrafted during the previous few months. These clients
are likely representative of a substantial population of marginal overdrafters
in Turkey, and they share key characteristics with “banked” populations in
both more- and less-developed countries.
The experimental design produces random variation, both across clients
and over time, in overdraft prices and in messaging content, frequency, and
duration (see Figure 1). Our tests rely on overdraft usage comparisons across
groups receiving different promotions, since Turkish banks frequently use

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT