Toward an integrated theory of the firm: The interplay between internal organization and vertical integration

AuthorJorge Tarziján,Francisco Brahm
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2446
Date01 December 2016
Published date01 December 2016
Strategic Management Journal
Strat. Mgmt. J.,37: 2481–2502 (2016)
Published online EarlyView 17 November2015 in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com) DOI: 10.1002/smj.2446
Received 20 May 2014;Final revision received28 August 2015
TOWARD AN INTEGRATED THEORY OF THE FIRM:
THE INTERPLAY BETWEEN INTERNAL
ORGANIZATION AND VERTICAL INTEGRATION
FRANCISCO BRAHM*and JORGE TARZIJÁN
School of Management, Pontificia Universidad Católica de Chile, Santiago, Chile
Research summary: Two centralissues in strategic management are the determination of a rm’s
internal delegation and its vertical boundaries. Despite the importance of these issues, there is
scant analysis concerning their interaction. Using a comprehensive database of the construction
industry, we show that vertical integration positively inuences the centralization decision and
that the main mechanism driving this relationship is an improvement in the hierarchically coor-
dinated adaptation of rm activities when complexity and uncertainty are high. We also observe
that centralization is negatively related to the extent of relational contracts between principals
and agents, and positively related to an exogenous increase in the cost of employee layoffs. Our
results suggest that managers cannot consider rm boundaries and internal organization to be
independent decisions.
Managerial summary: We ask whether a rm’s decision about vertically integrating or out-
sourcing its activities affects the choice of centralizing or delegating its internal decision-making
process. Our statistical analysis shows that rms with more vertical integrationtend to centralize
the decision-making process and that rms that outsource more tend to decentralize more. Why?
Vertical integration enables the use of centralized authority to coordinate activities that interact
intensively. Accordingly, we found that the positive inuence of vertical integration on central-
ization is especially signicant in more complex and uncertain environments, when the need for
coordination is higher. Thus, our results suggest that managers should choose vertical integration
considering its effect on internal decision-making processes, particularly when coordination is
important. Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
INTRODUCTION
A major body of literature within organiza-
tional economics considers the determination
of rm internal organization. A cornerstone of
this research examines the choice to centralize
decision-making at the top of the organization
or delegate it to lower level managers (Aghion,
Bloom, and Van Reenen, 2014; Argyres and
Keywords: centralization; vertical integration; adaptation;
agency costs; prior interactions
*Correspondence to: Francisco Brahm, Ponticia Universidad
Católica de Chile, School of Management, Vicuña Mackenna
4860, Santiago, Chile. E-mail: fbrahm@uc.cl
Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
Silverman, 2004). Another major body of literature
in this eld is concerned with the determination of
rm boundaries, that is, the make-or-buy decision
(Coase, 1937; Williamson, 1975, 1985). Despite
the importance of these bodies of literature, there
has been scant analysis of a possible interrela-
tionship between them. This void is noteworthy
because a sound theory of the rm requires an
understanding of how internal organization and
rm boundaries interact.1For example, if delega-
tion and outsourcing were complements, then for
1A third aspect that an integrated theory of the rm should account
for is heterogeneity of rm performance (Mahoney and Qian,
2013). We do not address this issue explicitlyin our article.
2482 F. Brahm and J. Tarziján
a given set of activities, we would observe either
delegation and outsourcing or centralization and
integration. A complementary relationship between
these organizational decisions is consistent with
theoretical arguments regarding the difculty of
integrating and then delegating (Baker, Gibbons,
and Murphy, 2001), but contradicts popular press
advice for empowerment and delegation regardless
of rm boundaries (Foss and Klein, 2014).
Calls to explore the internal organization and rm
boundaries jointly have been issued in the literature
(Acemoglu et al., 2007; Bidwell, 2012; Holmstrom,
1999). Garrouste and Saussier note, “In addition to
the questions regarding the nature and the bound-
aries of the rm, the theory of the rm should
also be able to cope with the question of inter-
nal organization.” (2005: 187). Received theory is
insufcient. The new property rights theory by Hart
and Moore (1990) posits that legal ownership of
assets involves complete centralization of decision
rights, that is, vertical integration and centraliza-
tion are largely inseparable.2In contrast, the trans-
action cost economics (TCE) perspective indicates,
“Substantially the same factors that are ultimately
responsible for market failures also explain failures
of internal organization” (Williamson, 1973: 316),
predicting that centralization and vertical integra-
tion will co-vary with transactional attributes, but
neglecting their direct mutual inuence. A multitask
principal-agent model (Holmstrom and Milgrom,
1994) assumes a pattern of tasks interdependence
that produces a positive relationship among central-
ization of authority, vertical integration, and lack
of incentives. However, assuming a pattern lim-
its the theory’s explanatory depth on the relation-
ships among these three governance instruments.
Makadok and Coff (2009) extend the multitask-
ing agency model to show that by altering the
assumed interdependence between tasks, the model
can account for a variety of organizational forms
combining different levels of centralization, verti-
cal integration, and incentives. However, the model
cannot predict which combinations are more preva-
lent. As Makadok and Coff indicate, “[our theory]
does not imply that every part of the governance
space is populated with viable forms. Indeed, some
parts of the space might be sparsely populated— or
2Attempts to extend the property rights model to include internal
organization have been made: Powell (2015) uses “inuence
costs,” Rajan and Zingales (1998) use “access to assets,” and Hart
and Holsmtrom (2010) use “reference points.”
even empty, when the particular combination of
governance elements is impractical, infeasible, or
unstable” (2009: 300).
There is some empirical evidence that sug-
gests a positive relationship between centralization
(delegation) and vertical integration (outsourcing)
(Alonso, Clifton, and Díaz-Fuentes, 2015; Arora,
Belenzon, and Rios, 2014; Chanson and Quelin,
2013; Hong, Kueng, and Yang, 2015; McElheran,
2014; Weigelt and Miller, 2013; Whittington et al.,
1999). However, this evidence is correlational, and
thus, cannot speak to whether these two deci-
sions co-vary because of transaction character-
istics, as TCE would predict, or whether there
is a specic interdependence between them that
would inform Makadok and Coff (2009)’s question
regarding the feasibility of organizational forms.
The distinction between transaction characteristics
and complementarity of governance instruments
is empirically important. For instance, Novak and
Stern (2009) show that the effect of complementar-
ity in vertical integration decisions is at least as rele-
vant as the impact of the transaction characteristics.
We contribute to this literature by providing a
focused empirical analysis of the impact of verti-
cal integration on centralization. In particular, we
use appropriate instruments to evaluate the causal
impact of vertical integration on centralization. This
approach enables us to evaluate whether vertical
integration correlates with centralization or whether
it exerts a causal inuence. By contrasting the
impact of vertical integration on centralization with
other canonical drivers (drawn from transaction
characteristics), we can evaluate whether the inter-
dependency is economically meaningful compared
to these drivers. Finally, although some generaliz-
ability may be sacriced, our approach permits us
to (1) provide detailed evidence that corroborates
a suggestive pattern found in previous studies, (2)
distinguish the mechanisms that might be driving
the results, and (3) spur theoretical work that is
needed to develop a theory that jointly addresses
rm boundaries and internal organization.
Weproceed by introducing the two main determi-
nants of the centralization decision, namely, adapta-
tion costs and agency costs. To predict the impact
of vertical integration on centralization, we dis-
cuss how vertical integration may affect the adapta-
tion and agency costs of the centralization choice.
Then, we estimate the impact of vertical integra-
tion on centralization. To explore the mechanisms
that may be driving the results, we evaluate whether
Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,37: 2481–2502 (2016)
DOI: 10.1002/smj

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT