Time‐Varying Asset Volatility and the Credit Spread Puzzle

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12765
AuthorDU DU,REDOUANE ELKAMHI,JAN ERICSSON
Date01 August 2019
Published date01 August 2019
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXIV, NO. 4 AUGUST 2019
Time-Varying Asset Volatility and the Credit
Spread Puzzle
DU DU, REDOUANE ELKAMHI, and JAN ERICSSON
ABSTRACT
Most extant structural credit risk models underestimate credit spreads—a shortcom-
ing known as the credit spread puzzle. We consider a model with priced stochastic
asset risk that is able to fit medium- to long-term spreads. The model, augmented by
jumps to help explain short-term spreads, is estimated on firm-level data and identi-
fies significant asset variance risk premia. An important feature of the model is the
significant time variation in risk premia induced by the uncertainty about asset risk.
Variousextensions are considered, among them optimal leverage and endogenous de-
fault.
STRUCTURAL CREDIT RISK MODELS HAVE MET WITH SIGNIFICANT difficulties in aca-
demic research. First, attempts to empirically implement models on individual
corporate bond prices have failed.1Second, efforts to calibrate models to ob-
servable moments including historical default rates and Sharpe ratios have
been unable to match average credit spreads levels (the credit spread puzzle;
Huang and Huang (2012)). Finally, models have been unable to jointly explain
dynamics of credit spreads and equity volatilities (Huang and Zhou (2008)).
An important recent insight is that model improvements are likely to
come from modeling risk premia rather than default probabilities (Chen,
Du Du is with the City University Hong Kong. Redouane Elkamhi is with the Rotman School of
Management at the University of Toronto. Jan Ericsson is with Desautels Faculty of Management
at McGill University. Min Jiang contributed to an earlier version of this paper. Ericsson has ben-
efited from financial support from a Desmarais Faculty Scholarship, from the Institut de Finance
Math´
ematique de Montr´
eal, as well as SSHRC. Du has benefited from financial support by the
National Natural Science Foundation of China (No. 71720107002). The paper has benefited from
comments by seminar participants at Case WesternReserve University, HEC Montreal, Hong Kong
University of Science and Technology, University of Houston, University of Iowa, Konstanz Uni-
versity, National University of Singapore, and University of Toronto and conference participants
at the 9th International Paris Finance Meeting 2011, ITAM 2012, Tremblant Risk Management
2012, Risk Management Conference NUS 2011, SKK, IFSID 2012, Montreal, and Affi 2016, Li`
ege.
Special thanks to David Bates, Peter Christoffersen, Sudipto Dasgupta, Jin Chuan Duan, Adlai
Fisher (discussant), Santiago Garc´
ıa Verd´
u, Kris Jacobs, Chanik Jo, Aytek Malkhozov, Franck
Moraux (discussant), Raunaq Pungaliya, Tom Rietz, Sheikh Sadik, Ashish Tiwari, Anand Vijh,
Hao Wang, and Hao Zhou (discussant). We thank Evan Zhou for exceptional research assistance.
The authors have read the Journal of Finance’s disclosure policy and have no conflicts of interest
to declare.
1See Jones, Mason, and Rosenfeld (1984) and Eom, Helwege, and Huang (2004).
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12765
1841
1842 The Journal of Finance R
Collin-Dufresne, and Goldstein (2009, CCG)). Building on this insight, we de-
velop a structural model with time-varying priced asset volatility to explain
levels and dynamics of both credit spreads and equity volatilities. Our first
contribution is to show that, in calibrations, a reasonable unlevered asset
variance risk premium (AVRP) allows our model to match spread levels for
medium and longer maturities without difficulty. Our second contribution is
to estimate a stochastic volatility jump-diffusion (SVJ) model on firm-level
data for default swap spreads and equity volatility. We identify an economi-
cally significant AVRP and find that modeling priced stochastic asset volatility
strongly improves the model’s ability to not only account for time variation in
equity volatility, but also explain the time series of default swap spread term
structures.
Recent empirical work on default swap spreads provides evidence suggestive
of an important role for stochastic and priced asset volatility in credit risk
modeling.2Although a compelling extension to a class of models that has been
around for almost 40 years, stochastic volatility (SV) has not garnered much
attention in the credit risk literature. We present semi–closed-form (up to a
Fourier Inversion) solutions to debt and equity prices in a stochastic asset
volatility framework where default is triggered by a default boundary, as in
Black and Cox (1976), Longstaff and Schwartz (1995), and Collin-Dufresne and
Goldstein (2001).3In a model with SV, different aspects of variance dynamics
influence credit spreads. However, by far, the strongest effect arises from the
market price of asset volatility risk.
To illustrate this point, we replicate the Huang and Huang (2012)andChen
Collin-Dufresne and Goldstein (2009) calibrations. We confirm that, in the
absence of stochastic asset risk, our model replicates the credit spread puzzle.
Without a risk premium on asset variance, the model faces the same problem
that past studies have struggled with—it is hard to generate sufficiently high
spreads. The presence of stochastic variance per se does not help sufficiently in
2Huang and Zhou (2008) test a broad set of structural models and show the models’ inability
to fit the dynamics of credit default swap prices and equity volatilities. In particular, they find
that the models have difficulty generating sufficient time variation in equity volatility, suggesting
that an extension allowing for stochastic asset volatility is desirable. Zhang, Zhou, and Zhu (2009)
perform an empirical study of the effect of volatility and jumps on default swap prices. Their results
also point to the importance of modeling time-varying volatility. Further evidence is provided in
Wang, Zhou, and Zhou (2013), who show that not only are equity variance levels important for the
price of default protection, but the associated risk premium is also a key determinant of firm-level
credit spreads. Given this evidence, financial leverage would have to be the sole source of variation
in stock return volatility for asset volatility to be constant, as it is assumed to be in the majority
of structural credit risk models. Instead, recent empirical work by Choi and Richardsson (2016)
documents time variability in unlevered asset risk.
3Heston (1993) provides a closed-form solution for the price of a European option with Cox,
Ingersoll, and Ross’s (1985) dynamics for the variance. Fouque et al. (2003,2004,2011) introduce
perturbation techniques to address SV in a variety of option pricing settings. Related to our work,
Fouque et al. (2006) use a slow variation asymptotic approximation to a free boundary problem
with Gaussian variance dynamics to study defaultable securities. In the Internet Appendix, we
discuss these and other methodologies. The Internet Appendix may be found in the online version
of this article.
Time-Varying Asset Volatility and the Credit Spread Puzzle 1843
doing so. However, for reasonable parameter values governing the AVRP, our
model has no difficulty matching medium- to long-term spread levels. Because
short-term spreads remain hard to explain, consistent with previous work, we
introduce a jump component to our asset value dynamics using a specification
similartoPan(2002) that allows for a risk premium on jump-size uncertainty.4
To better understand this extension to our model, we conduct a calibration
exercise for a representative firm as we do for the SV case. We fix Sharpe ratios
and total volatility in our calibration. Note that introducing priced jumps affects
the amount of variance risk the model will bear—this would not matter if jump
and volatility risk were substitutes, but they influence different parts of the
term structure. We find a combination that does well in explaining spreads
across the term structure while allowing the model to fit both long- and short-
term default probabilities.
In addition to conducting calibration exercises for representative firms, we
run firm-by-firm estimations. In particular, we estimate firm-specific variance
risk premia using time series of default swap term structures and option-
implied volatilities for a cross section of firms with a variety of industry and
credit rating characteristics. The estimations require identification of the dy-
namics of asset values, volatilities, and jumps, all of which are unobservable.
We estimate physical and risk-adjusted firm value, volatility, and jump dynam-
ics using a simulated maximum likelihood (ML) methodology.
Tothe best of our knowledge, we provide the first estimates of firm-level asset
variance and jump dynamics together with their risk premia in the literature.
We obtain a broad range of estimates for the AVRP that are negative and sta-
tistically significant for a large majority of firms. The implied mean equity vari-
ance risk premium (EVRP) is 16.7%, with 5% and 95% percentiles of 44%
and 1.5%, respectively. The average jump intensity estimate across firms is
1%, with a cross-sectional variation of 0.1% to 4.6%, which is plausible given
the variation in credit ratings in our sample. The risk-adjusted jump size is
significant for the majority of firms, with an average of 81% of asset value.5
It is important to note that, in addition to explaining credit spread levels, our
model fits the level of equity volatility. Likelihood ratio tests show that our SV
model strongly dominates the nested constant volatility case.
To benchmark the level of our estimates, we translate them into an EVRP
that we compare with extant literature. The closest paper to our specification
is Pan (2002), who produces equity index-level estimates. Given the diversifi-
cation provided by an index, estimates for the index variance risk premium
4Since the advent of reduced-form credit models (see, e.g., Duffie and Singleton (1999)) that
are based on jumps-to-default, it has been noted that diffusion-based models generate insufficient
short-term spreads. Duffie and Lando (2001) find that jumps-to-default arise endogenously in a
structural model when asset values cannot be observed precisely and that this helps generate
significant short-term spreads. Collin-Dufresne, Goldstein, and Yang (2012) introduce jumps into
a structural model for credit index spreads for precisely this reason.
5In the Internet Appendix, we report on the estimation of the nested SV case and find that
the inclusion of jumps does not significantly change the estimates of the parameters of the volatil-
ity dynamics.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT