The Wall Street Walk when Blockholders Compete for Flows

AuthorGIORGIA PIACENTINO,AMIL DASGUPTA
Date01 December 2015
Published date01 December 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12308
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXX, NO. 6 DECEMBER 2015
The Wall Street Walk when Blockholders
Compete for Flows
AMIL DASGUPTA and GIORGIA PIACENTINO
ABSTRACT
Effective monitoring by equity blockholders is important for good corporate gover-
nance. A prominent theoretical literature argues that the threat of block sale (“exit”)
can be an effective governance mechanism. Many blockholders are money managers.
We show that, when money managers compete for investor capital, the threat of exit
loses credibility, weakening its governance role. Money managers with more skin
in the game will govern more successfully using exit. Allowing funds to engage in
activist measures (“voice”) does not alter our qualitative results. Our results link
widely prevalent incentives in the ever-expanding money management industry to
the nature of corporate governance.
EQUITY BLOCKHOLDERS IN PUBLICLY traded corporations who are dissatisfied with
the actions of company management can sell their blocks—the so-called “Wall
Street Walk.” A growing theoretical literature starting with Admati and Pflei-
derer (2009) and Edmans (2009) argues that the Wall Street Walk can be an
effective form of governance. The exit of a blockholder will typically depress
the stock price, punishing management whenever executive compensation is
linked to the market price of equity. Thus, faced with a credible threat of exit,
management will be reluctant to underperform. Admati and Pfleiderer argue
that, when blockholders observe managers underperforming, it is in their own
interest to exit early before information about the manager’s underperformance
becomes public. This makes exit a credible threat that ameliorates managerial
underperformance and enhances firm value. Edmans argues that informed in-
stitutional trading enhances the informational efficiency of the firm’s equity in
Dasgupta is at the London School of Economics, and is affiliated with CEPR and ECGI. Pia-
centino is at the Olin Business School at Washington University in St Louis. Wethank the referee,
Associate Editor, and Editor, Cam Harvey, for insightful input. We are grateful to Ulf Axelson,
Alon Brav, Elena Carletti, Alex Edmans, Simon Gervais, Oliver Hart, Wei Jiang, Arvind Krish-
namurthy, Yan Li, Xuewen Liu, Mark Lowenstein, Andrey Malenko, Gustavo Manso, David Reeb,
Zacharias Sautner, Rik Sen, Anand Srinivasan, Dimitri Vayanos, Michela Verardo, Ernst Ludvig
von Thadden, Liyan Yang, and audiences at AFA 2013, Amsterdam, Cambridge, Duke Fuqua,
EUI Florence, FIRS 2012, HKUST, Imperial, Leicester, LSE, Mannheim, Northwestern Kellogg,
Nottingham, NUS, Rome Tor Vergata, Stockholm, Tilburg, WFA 2012, the 5th Conference of the
Paul Woolley Centre, and UCL for helpful comments. We thank the Paul Woolley Centre at LSE
for financial support. Dasgupta thanks the Faculty of Economics at Cambridge University for its
kind hospitality. We have read The Journal of Finance’s disclosure policy and have no conflicts of
interest to disclose.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12308
2853
2854 The Journal of Finance R
the secondary market, enabling myopic managers to make better investment
decisions.
The theoretical literature on exit treats the blockholder as a profit-
maximizing principal: she acts as an individual owner of an equity block would.
In contrast, a significant proportion of equity blocks is held by delegated port-
folio managers who manage money for others (for example, mutual funds and
hedge funds).1This matters because money managers often face short-term
incentives that may lead them to behave in ways that are not conducive to
good corporate governance. For example, as the European Commission’s 2011
Green Paper “The EU Corporate Goverence Framework” notes (p. 12–13),
It appears that the way asset managers’ performance is evalu-
ated...encourages asset managers to seek short-term benefits ...The
Commission believes that short-term incentives ...maycontributesignif-
icantly to asset managers’ short-termism, which probably has an impact
on shareholder apathy.
An important reason why money managers may not take a long-term view
is that their investors chase short-term performance, which generates well-
documented short-term flow-performance relationships.2In this paper we build
on Admati and Pfleiderer (2009) to study how the presence of (endogenous)
short-term flow-performance relationships affects the ability of delegated block-
holders to govern via the threat of exit. Our key observation is that, when funds
differ in stock picking ability,exit may be informative about the fund manager ’s
skill and thus affect investor flows. We show that this signaling role of exit
impairs its disciplinary potential. The perverse effect of flow-performance rela-
tionships operates through both linear assets under management (AUM) fees
and convex performance fees (carried interest or “carry”)—the two components
of standard “two and twenty” contracts. Thus, common contractual arrange-
ments in money management foster endogenous short-termism and impair the
effectiveness of exit. We show that offsetting, long-term incentives arise from
the degree to which the fund manager self-invests in her fund: whether a money
manager can successfully govern via the threat of exit depends on the degree
to which she has skin in the game.
We analyze a three-date model with many funds, investors, and firms. Each
fund uses a combination of investor capital and proprietary resources (self-
investment) to hold a block in a firm. Funds are compensated via a combination
of AUM fees and carried interest. At the initial date, each firm manager takes
1Institutional money managers hold over 70% of U.S. equity (see, for example, Gillan and
Starks (2007)), and a significant measure of these holdings is quite concentrated. For example,
Hawley and Williams (2007) show that, in 2005, the 100 largest U.S. institutions owned 52% of
publicly held equity. Gopalan (2008) notes that in 2001 almost 60% of NYSE-listed firms had an
institutional blockholder with at least 5% equity ownership.
2See, for example, Brown, Harlow, and Starks (1996) and Chevalier and Ellison (1997,1999)
for mutual funds, and Agarwal, Daniel, and Naik (2009) and Lim, Sensoy,and Weisbach (2013)for
hedge funds.
The Wall Street Walk 2855
actions that affect firm performance. Each fund can observe whether the man-
ager of the company in which she owns a block underperforms and may then
sell the block at the interim date before the market learns about managerial
actions. At the final date, uncertainty resolves and consumption occurs.
Funds differ in their ability as stock pickers. Funds that are good stock pick-
ers are more likely to invest in companies with better corporate governance.
In such companies, management is less likely to underperform, making block-
holder exit less likely to be necessary. Investors observe the returns generated
by all funds at the interim date, make inferences about stock picking ability,
and allocate their money accordingly.The inferences about funds’ stock picking
ability are relevant because, following the interim date, funds have access to
further investment opportunities, the quality of which are again determined
by their stock picking skills: good stock pickers have access to better opportu-
nities. Accordingly, investors rationally use the interim performance of funds
to make capital allocation decisions.
Suppose that a fund—after acquiring a block in a company—observes that
management is underperforming. The fund can either sell her block in the
underperforming company at the interim date (that is, exit) or wait until the
final date. If she sells early, she may be able to hide her trade behind market
noise and sell her block at a price not reflecting the full reduction in value
implied by management underperformance. If she waits and sells later, she
will liquidate her block at a lower price. Thus, to the extent that the fund
cares directly about her portfolio value due to her self-investment, she will be
inclined to exit.
However, the fund may also be concerned about inferences made in the short
term by investors, which may affect her payoffs via endogenous flows. If she
sells the block early,she will hurt her short-term return relative to other funds,
causing an earlier loss of investor flow. In contrast, if she does not sell her block
early but some other funds do, her short-term return relative to others will
be improved—she will not only keep her own investors, but may also attract
investors from other funds (who may have sold their underperforming blocks
early and thus underperformed). Of course, there will be a price to pay later
in terms of lowered liquidation value. In the meanwhile, however, the fund
will earn AUM fees by retaining her own investors and attracting new ones.
Selling the block early also reduces carried interest: not only will a sale reduce
current carry by lowering today’s marked-to-market portfolio value, but, due
to endogenous outflows, it will also reduce fund size, and thereby limit access
to new investments and reduce future carry. Thus, given flow-performance
relationships, the presence of AUM fees and carried interest discourages funds
from exiting.
Our main result (Proposition 2) formalizes this trade-off. We show that, when
delegated blockholders do not have sufficient self-investment, and when good
and bad funds are sufficiently different (so that investors chase performance),
the threat of exit cannot be credible in equilibrium. The applied implication
of our result is that funds’ ability to govern via exit will be determined by the
relative strength of contractual incentives and self-investment. For a given

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT