The WACC Fallacy: The Real Effects of Using a Unique Discount Rate

Published date01 June 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12250
AuthorDAVID THESMAR,AUGUSTIN LANDIER,PHILIPP KRÜGER
Date01 June 2015
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXX, NO. 3 JUNE 2015
The WACC Fallacy: The Real Effects of Using
a Unique Discount Rate
PHILIPP KR ¨
UGER, AUGUSTIN LANDIER, and DAVID THESMAR
ABSTRACT
In this paper, we test whether firms properly adjust for risk in their capital budget-
ing decisions. If managers use a single discount rate within firms, we expect that
conglomerates underinvest (overinvest) in relatively safe (risky) divisions. We mea-
sure division relative risk as the difference between the division’s asset beta and a
firm-wide beta. We establish a robust and significant positive relationship between
division-level investment and division relative risk. Next, we measure the value loss
due to this behavior in the context of acquisitions. When the bidder’s beta is lower
than that of the target, announcement returns are significantly lower.
IN THIS PAPER,WE PROVIDE evidence that firms fail to properly adjust for risk in
their valuation of investment projects, and that such behavior leads to value-
destroying investment decisions. According to the standard textbook formula,
the value of an investment project depends on both its expected cash flows
and its discount rate, which is a measure of risk. In practice, however, survey
evidence shows that most firms use only a single discount rate to value all of
their projects (Bierman (1993), Graham and Harvey (2001)), a behavior that
we label the “WACC fallacy.” The weighted average cost of capital (WACC)
fallacy is a failure to account for project-specific risk, which is particularly
damaging when the firm has to decide between heterogeneous projects. The
value of riskier projects will be overestimated, while that of safer ones will be
underestimated.
We expect the WACC fallacy to have real effects: in relatively complex firms,
investment will be biased against safe projects, which should lead to the
Kr¨
uger is with the University of Geneva (Geneva School of Economics and Management
and Geneva Finance Research Institute); Landier is with the Toulouse School of Economics; and
Thesmar is with HEC Paris and CEPR. The authors greatly appreciate comments and suggestions
from Malcolm Baker, Andor Gy¨
orgy, Owen Lamont, Oliver Spalt, Masahiro Watanabe, Jeff Wur-
gler, and seminar participants at AFA,CEPR, EFA, EFMA, and NBER meetings, HBS, Mannheim
University,Geneva University, and HEC Lausanne. The authors also thank three referees, the Ed-
itor (Cambell Harvey), and an Associate Editor for their constructive suggestions. Kr¨
uger thanks
Gen`
eve Place Financi`
ere for financial support. Landier acknowledges financial support from a
Scor Chair at the JJ Laffont foundation and from the European Research Council under the Euro-
pean Community’s Seventh Framework Programme (FP7/2007-2013) Grant Agreement no. 312503
SolSys. Thesmar thanks the HEC Foundation for financial support.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12250
1253
1254 The Journal of Finance R
destruction of value as capital is not optimally used. The economic magni-
tude of this bias is potentially large. For example, suppose that a firm invests
in a project that pays a dollar in perpetuity. If it takes a discount rate of 10%,
the present value of the project is $10. By contrast, a rate of 8% would imply a
present value of $12.5. Hence, underestimating the discount rate by only two
percentage points leads to overestimating the project’s present value by 25%.
The present paper is a first attempt to document and measure the distortions
induced by the WACC fallacy by relying entirely on field data. To implement
our empirical tests, we focus on two types of projects: investment within con-
glomerates, and mergers and acquisitions.
First, we use business segment data to investigate the extent to which di-
versified firms rely on a firm-wide discount rate. To do so, we examine whether
diversified companies are inclined to invest less in their low-beta divisions than
in their high-beta divisions, controlling for standard determinants of invest-
ment, such as growth opportunities. The intuition is as follows. A company
using a single firm-wide discount rate will tend to overestimate the value of a
project whenever the project is riskier than the typical project of the company.
If companies apply the net present value (NPV) principle to allocate capital
across divisions,1then they will tend to overestimate the value of projects that
are riskier than the firm’s typical project and vice versa. This, in turn, should
lead to overinvestment (underinvestment) in divisions that have a beta above
(below) that of the firm’s representative project.
Using a large sample of divisions in diversified firms, we show in the first
part of the paper that investment in noncore divisions is robustly positively
related to the difference between the cost of capital of the division and that of
the most important division in the conglomerate (core division). We interpret
this finding as evidence that some firms discount investment projects from
noncore divisions using a discount rate close to the core division’s cost of capital.
We next discuss the cross-sectional determinants of this relationship and find
evidence consistent with models of bounded rationality: whenever making a
WACC mistake is more costly (e.g., the noncore division is large, the CEO has
sizable ownership, or within-conglomerate diversity in the cost of capital is
high), the measured behavior is less prevalent.
In the second part of the paper, we examine the present value loss induced
by evaluating projects using a single company-wide discount rate. To do so, we
focus on diversifying acquisitions, a particular class of investment projects that
are large, can be observed accurately, and whose value impact can be assessed
via event study methodology. We look at the market reaction to the acquisition
announcement of a bidder whose cost of capital is lower than that of the target.
If this bidder uses its own WACC to value the target, it tends to overvalue the
target, and thus announcement returns should be relatively poorer, reflecting
relatively lower shareholder value creation. We find that such behavior leads to
a relative loss of about 0.8% of the bidder’s market capitalization. On average,
1Survey evidence of CEOs and CFOs presented in Graham, Harvey, and Puri (2014) suggests
that the NPV ranking is the predominant principle governing capital budgeting decisions.
The WACC Fallacy 1255
this corresponds to about 8% of the deal value, or $16 million per deal. This
finding is robust to the inclusion of different control variables and to the use of
different specifications.
Following Stein (1996), our approach is connected with the idea that betas re-
sulting from the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) capture some dimension of
fundamental risk. On the positive side, our investment regressions show that,
irrespective of whether the CAPM holds, managers do use CAPM betas but fail
to adjust them across projects. Most corporate finance textbooks recommend
the use of CAPM betas to compute discount rates, but require that managers
use project-specific betas. Our investment regressions show that investment
in noncore divisions depends strongly on core betas. Hence, managers do use
a CAPM beta to make capital budgeting decisions, even if they use the wrong
one (core instead of noncore). On the normative side, our M&A results suggest
that using the wrong beta to value the NPV of an acquisition is value destroy-
ing. This may come as a surprise given that the CAPM fails to predict stock
returns. As shown in Stein (1996), however, this empirical failure is not in-
consistent with the normative prescriptions of textbooks. Indeed, CAPM-based
capital budgeting is value-creating if CAPM betas contain at least some infor-
mation on fundamental risk relevant for long-term investors. Our mergers and
acquisitions (M&A) results suggest that they do.
Our paper is related to several streams of research in corporate finance.
First, it contributes to the literature on the theory and practice of capital
budgeting and mergers and acquisitions. Graham and Harvey (2001) provide
survey evidence regarding firms’ capital budgeting, capital structure, and cost
of capital choices. Most relevant to our study, they show that firms tend to use
a firm-wide risk premium instead of a project-specific one when evaluating new
investment projects. Relying entirely on observed firm-level investment behav-
ior, our study is the first to test the real consequences of the finding in Graham
and Harvey (2001) that few firms use project-specific discount rates. More pre-
cisely, we provide evidence that the use of a single firm-wide discount rate
(the WACC fallacy) does in fact have statistically and economically significant
effects on capital allocation and firm value. Since we assume that managers
rely on the NPV criterion, the present paper is also related to Graham, Harvey,
and Puri (2014), who show that the NPV rule is the dominant way to allocate
capital across divisions. The same reasoning, however, also applies to firms
using an internal rate of return (IRR) criterion: if the minimum IRR required
for projects is similar across all the firm’s projects, there will be overinvest-
ment in risky projects. Thus, regardless of whether firms base decisions on
NPV or IRR, the use of a single rate leads to a similarly biased investment
policy.
Second, our paper contributes to the growing behavioral corporate finance
literature. Baker, Ruback, and Wurgler (2007) propose a taxonomy organizing
this literature around “irrational investors” versus “irrational managers.” The
more developed irrational-investors stream assumes that arbitrage is imper-
fect and that rational managers, in their corporate finance decisions, exploit

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT