The Value of Central Clearing

AuthorGUILLAUME VUILLEMEY
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12902
Published date01 August 2020
Date01 August 2020
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXV, NO. 4 AUGUST 2020
The Value of Central Clearing
GUILLAUME VUILLEMEY
ABSTRACT
I study a contracting innovation that suddenly insulated traders of hedging contracts
against counterparty risk: central clearing counterparties (CCPs) for derivatives. The
first CCP was created in Le Havre (France) in 1882, in the coffee futures market.
Using triple difference-in-differences estimation, I show that central clearing changed
the geography of trade flows Europe-wide, to the benefit of Le Havre. Inspecting
the mechanism using trader-level data, I find that the CCP solved both a “missing
market” problem and adverse selection issues. Central clearing also facilitated entry
of new traders in the market. The successful contracting innovation quickly spread
to other exchanges.
FINANCIAL FRICTIONS CAN PREVENT GAINS from trade from being realized and thus
resources from being efficiently allocated. However, whether financial frictions
impair trade is not exogenous: agents can design contracts to mitigate or undo
their effects (Allen and Gale (1988)). Throughout history, a number of contract-
ing innovations—from the bill of exchange to limited liability—improved cap-
ital allocation and risk-sharing, thus contributing to long-term growth (North
(1991)). Yet empirically identifying the causal impact of contracting innova-
tions on resource allocation is challenging. In particular, it is often difficult to
precisely date the appearance of contracting forms that are now widespread in
financial markets, and data to study these events are often lacking.
In this paper, I study a contracting innovation that has become essential in
present-day financial markets, namely, central clearing counterparties (CCPs)
for derivatives. As an experiment, I use the creation of the Caisse de Liquida-
tion des Affaires en Marchandises (CLAM) in the market for coffee futures in
Le Havre (France) in 1882. The contracting innovation brought about by the
Guillaume Vuillemey is at HEC Paris and CEPR. I am grateful to the editor (Philip Bond);
an associate editor; an anonymous referee; Patrice Baubeau; Bruno Biais; Jean-Edouard Col-
liard; Laura Rischbieter; seminar participants at University of Melbourne, Cleveland Fed, Ohio
State University, University of Rochester, Arizona State University, University of Amsterdam,
HEC Paris, and Paris School of Economics; and conference participants at the 4 Nations’ Cup
(ESMT), FIRS 2019, EFA 2019, and ACPR Workshopfor comments. I thank the Chair ACPR/Risk
Foundation: Regulation and Systemic Risk, Investissements d’Avenir (ANR-11-IDEX-0003/Labex
Ecodec/ANR-11-LABX-0047), and ANR (FIRR) for supporting this work. I have read The Journal
of Finance disclosure policy and have no conflicts of interest to disclose.
Correspondence: Guillaume Vuillemey, Department of Finance, HEC Paris, 1 Rue de la
Lib´
eration, Jouy-en-Josas 78351, France; e-mail: vuillemey@hec.fr.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12902
C2020 the American Finance Association
2021
2022 The Journal of Finance R
CLAM is to fully insulate futures traders against counterparty risk. Specifi-
cally, for the first time, a clearing institution interposed itself between traders,
becoming a buyer to any seller and a seller to any buyer, so as to guarantee
the execution of contracts. Before 1882, earlier clearinghouses, for example, in
Liverpool or New York, only offered netting services to facilitate the settlement
of transactions. The contracting arrangement invented by coffee traders in Le
Havre quickly spread worldwide and, after the 2008 financial crisis, central
clearing became mandatory globally for standardized derivatives.
I hand-collect rich archive data and conduct empirical analysis that yields
two contributions. The first is to show that greater risk-sharing opportunities
with derivatives had a significant causal impact on trade flows in underlying
commodities. The creation of the CLAM arguably satisfies exogeneity require-
ments, as it did not follow any pre-trend in trade flows in Le Havre, and it
was heavily debated by traders who did not foresee its impact on trade flows.
For identification, I estimate a triple difference-in-differences model. The three
sources of variation in trade flows that I exploit are (i) before and after 1882,
(ii) between Le Havre and other European markets where clearing is not in-
troduced and, (iii) within Le Havre, between coffee and other commodities that
remain uncleared. The specification enables many confounding factors, such
as commodity-specific and harbor-specific demand and supply shocks, to be
ruled out.
The estimation results show a positive and significant effect of the introduc-
tion of central clearing on coffee trade flows in Le Havre. I first estimate the
triple difference-in-differences model within France, comparing trade flows in
Le Havre with 22 other harbors. I find that the share of coffee imports enter-
ing France in Le Havre increased by 11.1 percentage points relative to control
commodities. I address residual endogeneity concerns by replicating the esti-
mation with cotton trade flows. Although the CLAM was created to mitigate
counterparty risk on coffee futures, it also accepted clearing of cotton futures.
In this case, the creation of the CLAM was exogenous to conditions in the cotton
market. Yet the results continue to hold when focusing on cotton trade flows,
using other textiles as a control.
Next, I extend my analysis to the European scale, reconstructing trade flows
in cleared and control commodities for seven countries. I show that central
clearing changed the geography of trade flows Europe-wide: after 1882, a sig-
nificantly larger share of coffee entered Europe in Le Havre, was warehoused
there, and eventually reexported to neighboring countries. The share of coffee
imports from France by the sample countries increased by 2.9 to 7.3 percentage
points, relative to control commodities. I also provide suggestive evidence that
larger inventories of coffee in Le Havre helped smoothing coffee consumption
in France. Finally, I support the quantitative results above with narrative evi-
dence. Many contemporaries wrote that the CLAM boosted trade in Le Havre
and, within 10 years, nine other European futures exchanges had introduced
CCPs. Therefore, the contracting innovation spread quickly. The focus on trade
flows distinguishes the paper from earlier work by Bernstein, Hughson, and
The Value of Central Clearing 2023
Weidenmier (2019), who study the impact of clearing on the pricing of counter-
party risk.
As a second contribution, I pin down the mechanism through which cen-
tral clearing affected trade flows. The main claim is that central clearing in-
creased the ability of coffee dealers to hedge their inventories. This in turn
induced them to import more coffee, warehouse it until it is demanded for
consumption, and re-export it. For this mechanism to explain the findings,
several requirements must be met. Most importantly, it must be the case that
hedging markets dysfunction before central clearing, and restart afterward.
Consistent with this idea, I show that central clearing was introduced fol-
lowing a global crisis in coffee markets in 1880, during which counterparty
risk impaired hedging possibilities. I then show that the CLAM was explicitly
designed to mitigate counterparty risk, with high equity, high margin require-
ments, and a chairman of the board with a strong reputation for honesty. A
last requirement for the improvement in hedging technology to explain the re-
sults is that traders make use of the CCP. Remarkably, even though use of the
CLAM was costly and not mandatory,an overwhelming majority of traders were
using it.
I then distinguish between two channels through which hedging possibili-
ties could increase. A first possibility is that, before central clearing, traders
were willing to hedge against the default risk of their counterparties, but in-
struments to do so were missing. Under this argument, the CCP solved the
“missing market” problem and thus made derivatives better hedging instru-
ments. To test for this channel, I study changes in the composition of the pool
of established traders around the introduction of the CLAM, using trader-level
data on coffee transactions. If the main friction before central clearing is the
existence of a missing market, then trading should concentrate among traders
with a low observable probability of default. Consistent with this idea, I find
that the share of low-quality traders, defined as traders exiting the market
within the next two years, was low before the CLAM (8.2%). Furthermore, it
did not increase with its creation, while trading volume in futures increased
massively (by 303% within six months). Thus, for established traders, a missing
market problem was preventing hedging ex ante.
A second possibility is that central clearing mitigated an adverse selection
problem: before the CLAM was in place, traders were unable to distinguish
between high- and low-quality counterparties, which impaired futures trad-
ing. I provide several pieces of evidence consistent with adverse selection being
significant for a subset of traders. To begin, there is evidence that the system
that prevailed before central clearing, under which futures trading was un-
collateralized and based on reputation, dysfunctioned during the 1880 crisis:
it became harder to distinguish between high- and low-quality traders based
solely on reputation. Traders designed a CCP to separate trader types by re-
quiring costly collateral to be posted. In this context, central clearing was the
most cost-efficient mechanism to require collateral, due to its netting bene-
fits. Additionally, I provide econometric evidence that adverse selection was

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT